Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-gtxcr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T01:46:31.240Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Law, Policy, and Ethics of Employers' Use of Financial Incentives to Improve Health

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2021

Extract

Individuals can often take steps to preserve or improve their own health. They can eat appropriate quantities of healthy foods, exercise, and refrain from smoking. They can obtain preventive care and adhere to their physicians’ advice about how best to manage their health. But they often fail to take these steps.

A widespread failure to adopt healthy behaviors can significantly erode public health while increasing health care costs. Obesity, for example, increases the risk of heart disease, stroke, liver disease, and certain cancers. By one estimate, it is responsible for almost 10 percent of medical spending in the United States, or about $147 billion per year. Smoking increases the risk of heart disease, stroke, lung disease, and cancer; it accounts for nearly 20 percent of deaths each year in the United States and about $96 billion in health care expenditures.

Type
Symposium
Copyright
Copyright © American Society of Law, Medicine and Ethics 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, The Health Effects of Overweight and Obesity, available at <http://www.cdc.gov/healthyweight/efects/index.html> (last visited June 8, 2010).+(last+visited+June+8,+2010).>Google Scholar
Finkelstein, E. A. Trogdon, J. G. Cohen, J. W. Dietz, W., “Annual Medical Spending Attributable to Obesity: Payer- and Service-Specific Estimates,” Health Affairs 28, no. 5 (2009): W822–w831, at w822.Google Scholar
Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, “Smoking and Tobacco Use,” available at <http://www.cdc.gov/tobacco/data_statistics/fact_sheets/fast_facts/> (last visited June 8, 2011).+(last+visited+June+8,+2011).>Google Scholar
See Gertler, P., “Do Conditional Cash Transfers Improve Child Health? Evidence from PROGRESA's Control Randomized Experiment,” American Economic Review 94, no. 2 (2004): 336341. The program is now called Oportunidades. See “Oportunidades, A Human Development Program,” available at <http://www.oportunidades.gob.mx/Portal/wb/Web/oportunidades_a_human_development_program> (last visited June 8, 2011); Bate, P., “The Story Behind Oportunidades,” available at <http://www.iadb.org/idbamerica/index.cfm?thisid=3049> (last visited June 8, 2011).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Australian Government, “Payment Rates,” available at <http://www.centrelink.gov.au/internet/internet.nsf/payments/mat_rates.htm> (last visited June 8, 2011).+(last+visited+June+8,+2011).>Google Scholar
Greene, J., Medicaid Efforts to Incentivize Healthy Behaviors, Center for Health Care Strategies, Inc., Pub. 299 (July 2007), available at <http://www.chcs.org/usr_doc/Medicaid_Efforts_to_Incentivize_Healthy_Behaviors.pdf> (last visited June 8, 2011).+(last+visited+June+8,+2011).>Google Scholar
StickK, “The Smartest Way to Set and Achieve Your Goals,” available at <http://www.stickk.com> (last visited June 8, 2011).+(last+visited+June+8,+2011).>Google Scholar
Caudron, S., “Are Health Incentives Disincentives?” Personnel Journal 71, no. 8 (August 1992): 3540.Google Scholar
Priester, R., “Are Financial Incentives for Wellness Fair?” Employee Benefits Journal 17, no. 1 (March 1992): 3840, at 38 (noting results of 1990 survey); Christensen, R., “Employment-Based Health Promotion and Wellness Programs,” EBRI Notes 22, no. 7 (July 2001): 1–6, at 2 (describing results from the 1999 National Worksite Health Promotion Survey, conducted by the Association for Worksite Health Promotion, William M. Mercer, Inc., and the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services' Office of Disease Prevention and Health Promotion).Google Scholar
National Business Group on Health and Towers Watson, The Road Ahead: Shaping Health Care Strategy in a Post-Reform Environment (2011), at 15, available at <http://www.towerswatson.com/assets/pdf/3946/TowersWatson-NBGH-2011-NA-2010-18560.pdf> (last visited June 8, 2011).+(last+visited+June+8,+2011).>Google Scholar
See The White House, Fact Sheet: Innovative Workplace Practices: A Discussion with President Obama (May 12, 2009) (describing employer wellness initiatives and stating that “[t]he President hopes that by encouraging more employers to adopt similar programs, we can improve the productivity of our workforce, delay or avoid many of the complications of chronic diseases, and slow medical cost growth”), available at <http://www.whitehouse.gov/the_press_office/Fact-Sheet-Innovative-Workplace-Practices-A-Discussion-With-President-Obama/> (last visited June 8, 2011); Burd, S. A., “How Safeway Is Cutting Health-Care Costs,” Wall Street Journal, June 12, 2009 (describing Safeway wellness program initiatives and calling on the federal government to raise the ceiling that limits financial incentives); Hilzenrath, D. S., “Misleading Claims about Safeway Wellness Incentives Shape Health-Care Bill,” Washington Post, January 17, 2010 (describing how Safeway shaped legislative debate but suggesting that Safeway's experiences do not demonstrate that incentives prevent health care cost increases).+(last+visited+June+8,+2011);+Burd,+S.+A.,+“How+Safeway+Is+Cutting+Health-Care+Costs,”+Wall+Street+Journal,+June+12,+2009+(describing+Safeway+wellness+program+initiatives+and+calling+on+the+federal+government+to+raise+the+ceiling+that+limits+financial+incentives);+Hilzenrath,+D.+S.,+“Misleading+Claims+about+Safeway+Wellness+Incentives+Shape+Health-Care+Bill,”+Washington+Post,+January+17,+2010+(describing+how+Safeway+shaped+legislative+debate+but+suggesting+that+Safeway's+experiences+do+not+demonstrate+that+incentives+prevent+health+care+cost+increases).>Google Scholar
See 26 C.F.R. § 54.9802–1(f)(2)(i), 29 C.F.R. § 2590.702(f)(2) (i), 45 C.F.R. § 146.121 (f)(2)(i) (regulations imposing 20 percent ceiling); ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(A).Google Scholar
ACA § 4303, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 280l (technical assistance); ACA § 10408, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 280l note (grants for small businesses).Google Scholar
ACA § 4108 (allocating $100 million for grants to states to test incentive programs for Medicaid beneficiaries), to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 1396a note; ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(l) (mandating creation of a 10-state demonstration project involving wellness programs offered by issuers of policies sold in individual markets).Google Scholar
See Cawley, J. Ruhm, C., “The Economics of Risky Health Behaviors,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 17081 (2011), at 99100 (explaining how financial incentives can “help people help themselves” and observing that cash rewards “may help to solve…problems of salience, immediacy, and time-inconsistency.”).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
See, e.g., Laibson, D., “Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, no. 2 (1997): 443477. See also Cawley, Ruhm, , supra note 18, at 53–57 (describing economic literature on preferences and explaining its relevance to healthy behaviors).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
While this mechanism is more likely to be at work for rewards directed at very low income individuals, such as conditional cash transfer programs, it is possible that a financial reward for something like blood pressure control could help offset the costs associated with achieving it.Google Scholar
Furthermore, in Part III, we raise questions about the extent to which incentive programs redistribute resources.Google Scholar
Henke, R. M. Goetzel, R. Z. McHugh, J. Isaac, F., “Recent Experience in Health Promotion at Johnson & Johnson: Lower Health Spending, Strong Return on Investment,” Health Affairs 30, no. 3 (2011): 490–99, at 490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baicker, K. Cutler, D. Song, Z., “Workplace Wellness Programs Can Generate Savings,” Health Affairs 29, no. 2 (2010): 18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finkelstein, E. A. Linnan, L. A. Tate, D. F. Birken, B. E., “A Pilot Study Testing the Effect of Different Levels of Financial Incentives on Weight Loss among Overweight Employees,” Journal of Occupational and Environmental Medicine 49, no. 9 (2007): 981989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volpp, K. G. John, L. K. Troxel, A. B. Norton, L. Fassbender, J. Loewenstein, G., “Financial Incentive-Based Approach for Weight Loss: A Randomized Trial,” JAMA 300, no. 22 (2008): 26312637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Authors of a review of 47 articles published between 1966 and 2002 concerning consumer health incentives concluded that “consumer incentives are effective for simple preventive care and distinct behavioral goals that are well defined” but that there was not “sufficient evidence at this time to say that economic incentives are effective for promoting the long-term lifestyle changes required for health promotion.” Kane, R. L. Johnson, P. E. Town, R. J. Butler, M., Economic Incentives for Preventive Care: AHRQ Publication No. 04–E024–2 (August 2004), Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, Evidence Report/Technology Assessment No. 101, at vi. A more recent review of the financial incentive literature concluded that “research evidence suggests that incentives can increase adoption of healthy behaviors but that positive effects may diminish over time.” Sutherland, K. Christianson, J. B. Leather-Man, S., “Impact of Targeted Financial Incentives on Personal Health Behavior: A Review of the Literature,” Medical Care Research and Review 65, no. 6 (2008): 36S78SGoogle Scholar
Cahill, K. Perera, R., “Competitions and Incentives for Smoking Cessation,” Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews Issue 3 (2008).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volpp, K. G. Troxel, A. B. Pauly, M. V. Glick, G. A. Puig, A. Asch, D. A. Galvin, R. Zhu, J. Wan, F. DeGuzman, J. Corbett, E. Weiner, J. Audrain-McGovern, J., “A Randomized, Controlled Trial of Financial Incentives for Smoking Cessation,” New England Journal of Medicine 360, no. 7 (2009): 699709, at 707 (discussing limits of 2005 Cochrane Collaboration review).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. Brennan, T. Volpp, K. G., “Asymmetric Paternalism to Improve Health Behaviors,” JAMA 28, no. 20 (2007): 24152417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Id., at 2415.Google Scholar
Id., at 2416.Google Scholar
Volpp, K. G. Pauly, M. V. Loewenstein, G. Bangsberg, D., “P4P4P: An Agenda for Research on Pay-for-Performance for Patients,” Health Affairs 28, no. 1 (2009): 206214, at 210–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Id., at 211.Google Scholar
Harris Interactive, WSJ.com/Harris Interactive Survey Finds Drop in Public Support of Higher Healthcare Costs for Smokers or the Obese, Press Release, October 31, 2007. A small survey of patients in Philadelphia primary care clinics found a similarly mixed opinion about paying smokers to quit smoking or paying obese individuals to lose weight, although respondents were more supportive of incentive arrangements operated through insurance. Long, J. A. Helweg-Larsen, M. Volpp, K. G., “Patient Opinions Regarding ‘Pay for Performance for Patients,’” Journal of General Internal Medicine 23, no. 10 (2008): 16471652, at 1649.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gabel, J. R. Whitmore, H. Pickreign, J. Ferguson, C. C. Jain, A. Shova, K. C. Scherer, H., “Obesity and the Workplace: Current Programs and Attitudes among Employers and Employees,” Health Affairs 28, no. 1 (2009): 4656, at 49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
See, e.g., Rose, B., “Employers Experiment with Tough Get-Healthy Regimes,” Chicago Tribune (February 10, 2008) (“Few would argue it's OK for employers to dictate workers' lifestyles outside work….”).Google Scholar
Jesson, L., “Weighing the Wellness Programs: The Legal Implications of Imposing Personal Responsibility Obligations,” Virginia Journal of Social Policy and the Law 15, no. 2 (2008): 217298, at 266–268.Google Scholar
The Americans with Disabilities Act offers some protections for employees' health information. Under 29 C.F.R. § 1630.14, information “regarding the medical condition or history of any employee shall be collected and maintained on separate forms and in separate medical files and be treated as a confidential medical record…”.Google Scholar
“Annual Smoking-Attributable Mortality, Years of Potential Life Lost, and Economic Costs – United States, 1995–1999,” Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report 51, no. 14 (2002): 300303.Google Scholar
Finkelstein, E. Fiebelkorn, I. Wang, G., “The Costs of Obesity Among Full-Time Employees,” American Journal of Health Promotion 20, no. 1 (2005): 4551, at 49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thorpe, K. E. Florence, C. S. Howard, D. H. Joski, P., “Trends: The Impact of Obesity on Rising Medical Spending,” Health Affairs 23, supp. no. 2 (2004): W4–480–w4–486, at w4–480.Google Scholar
See, e.g., Okie, S., “The Employer as Health Coach,” New England Journal of Medicine 357, no. 15 (2007): 14651469 (noting that the corporate cafeteria at General Mills “offers many nutritious, low-calorie choices, including a subsidized salad bar”).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alderman, L., “Getting Healthy, with a Little Help from the Boss,” New York Times, May 23, 2009.Google Scholar
Heinen, L. Darling, H., “Addressing Obesity in the Workplace: The Role of Employers,” The Milbank Quarterly 87, no. 1 (2009): 101122, at 106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halpern, S. D. Madison, K. M. Volpp, K. G., “Patients As Mercenaries? The Ethics of Using Financial Incentives in the War on Unhealthy Behaviors,” Circulation: Cardiovascular Quality and Outcomes 2, no. 5 (2009): 514516.Google Scholar
For an article raising the possibility that employers could use health plan design to encourage sicker employees to seek insurance elsewhere, see generally Monahan, A. B. Schwarcz, D., “Will Employers Undermine Health Care Reform by Dumping Sick Employees?” Virginia Law Review 97, no. 1 (2011): 125197.Google Scholar
See Fennell, L. A., “Willpower Taxes,” Georgetown Law Journal 99 (forthcoming 2011): 1619 (discussing research on the exercise of willpower and noting that “willpower works like a muscle that can become fatigued with use” and that “self-control seems to share a common, limited, depletable fund with other cognitive tasks, such as decisionmaking”).Google Scholar
See, e.g., Sutherland, et al., supra note 27, at 41S (discussing implications of income for incentive program participation).Google Scholar
See Gabel, et al., supra note 39, at 52.Google Scholar
Pearson, S. D. Lieber, S. R., “Financial Penalties for the Unhealthy: Ethical Guidelines for Holding Employees Responsible for Their Health,” Health Affairs 28, no. 3 (2009): 845852, at 847.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Many commentators have stressed the importance of voluntariness in ethical program design. See, for example, Id., at 848849; Priester, , supra note 10, at 39.Google Scholar
In discussing the meaning of voluntariness, Priester has pointed to many such barriers: “The mere existence of alternative courses of action…should not count as proof that an individual's unhealthy action is free. Health habits are acquired within social groups (e.g., family, peers) and are often supported by powerful economic, political and cultural elements in the general society (e.g., advertising). In some instances, psychological factors may also preclude or impede authentic, reasoned choices.” Id. (Priester), at 39. See also Wikler, D., “Who Should Be Blamed for Being Sick?” Health Education Quarterly 14, no. 1 (1987): 1125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
See Pearson and Lieber, supra note 55, at 847849.Google Scholar
While the ACA does not mandate individual-specific standards for all employees, such standards would be consistent with the ACA's requirements for a “reasonable alternative standard” for individuals for whom “it is unreasonably difficult due to a medical condition to satisfy” or “it is medically inadvisable to attempt to satisfy” a health status factor-related standard. ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(D).Google Scholar
Jeffery, R. W. Thompson, P. D. Wing, R. R., “Effects on Weight Reduction of Strong Monetary Contracts for Calorie Restriction or Weight Loss,” Behaviour Research and Therapy 16, no. 5 (1978): 363369 (weight loss study).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
See Volpp, et al., supra note 29, at 706 (“Members of the incentive group who participated in a smoking-cessation program had significantly higher rates of cessation than did members of the control group who participated in such a program (46.3% vs. 20.8%, P=0.03).”).Google Scholar
See Gabel, et al., supra note 39, at 52.Google Scholar
See, e.g., Mariner, W. K., “Social Solidarity and Personal Responsibility in Health Reform,” Connecticut Insurance Law Journal 14, no. 2 (2008): 199228, at 217–218 (discussing experience of Clarian Health).Google Scholar
See Mello, M. M. Rosenthal, M. B., “Wellness Programs and Lifestyle Discrimination – the Legal Limits,” New England Journal of Medicine 359, no. 2 (2008): 192199, at 197 (noting that “sponsors may be able to gain traction by framing wellness incentives as penalties rather than rewards”); see Sutherland, et al., supra note 27, at 40s (discussing loss aversion in the context of incentive programs). An early contribution to this area of research was Kahneman, D. Tversky, A., “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk,” Econometrica 47, no. 2 (1979): 263–291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dudley, R. A. Tseng, C. Bozic, K. Smith, W. A. Luft, H. S., “Consumer Financial Incentives: A Decision Guide for Purchasers,” AHRQ Publication No. 07(08)-0059 (2007), at 17 (“There is no specific evidence from health services research to address whether consumer financial incentives should be structured as rewards, penalties, or a combination of the two.”).Google Scholar
See National Business Group on Health and Towers Watson, supra note 11, at 16.Google Scholar
Schmidt, H. Voigt, K. Wikler, D., “Carrots, Sticks, and Health Care Reform – Problems with Wellness Incentives,” New England Journal of Medicine 362, no. 2 (December 30, 2009): E3(1)-e3(3), at e3(3).Google Scholar
See, e.g., Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, s.v. “Coercion,” available at <http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/coercion/> (last visited June 9, 2011).+(last+visited+June+9,+2011).>Google Scholar
Grady, C., “Money for Research Participation: Does It Jeopardize Informed Consent?” American Journal of Bioethics 1, no. 2 (2001): 4044, at 40 (citing Beauchamp, T. Childress, J., Principles of Biomedical Ethics, 4th ed. [New York: Oxford University Press: 1994]: At 165).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wertheimer, A. Miller, F. G., “Payment for Research Participation: A Coercive Offer?” Journal of Medical Ethics 34, no. 5 (2008): 389392, at 390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
This assumes that the employees would collectively bear the full costs of their own health care. Assuming that the employer bears a particular percentage of these health care costs would not fundamentally alter the analysis.Google Scholar
See legal analysis in Part IV.Google Scholar
This analysis does not completely eliminate the possibility of health benefit-related coercion. Consider health risk assessments (HRAs), which collect information about employees' current health status, health risks, and health history, and serve as a foundation for many wellness programs. (See National Business Group on Health and Towers Watson, supra note 11, at 16.) The Americans with Disabilities Act (ADA) limits employers' ability to engage in disability-related inquiries, but allows “voluntary medical histories” as part of an employee health program. (42 U.S.C. § 12112(d)(4).) The Equal Employment Opportunity Commission (EEOC) has suggested informally that the ADA would forbid a penalty in the form of denial of insurance benefits to an employee who declines to respond to a health risk questionnaire containing questions seeking disability-related information. (Letter from Peggy Mastroianni, R., EEOC [March 6, 2009], available at <http://www.eeoc.gov/eeoc/foia/letters/2009/ada_disability_medexam_healthrisk.html> [last visited June 9, 2011].) The implication is that the EEOC views the provision of benefits as an appropriate baseline, such that a threat to deprive someone of these benefits if they refuse to complete an HRA has the potential to be coercive, rendering the medical history “involuntary.” [last visited June 9, 2011].) The implication is that the EEOC views the provision of benefits as an appropriate baseline, such that a threat to deprive someone of these benefits if they refuse to complete an HRA has the potential to be coercive, rendering the medical history “involuntary.”' href=https://scholar.google.com/scholar?q=This+analysis+does+not+completely+eliminate+the+possibility+of+health+benefit-related+coercion.+Consider+health+risk+assessments+(HRAs),+which+collect+information+about+employees'+current+health+status,+health+risks,+and+health+history,+and+serve+as+a+foundation+for+many+wellness+programs.+(See+National+Business+Group+on+Health+and+Towers+Watson,+supra+note+11,+at+16.)+The+Americans+with+Disabilities+Act+(ADA)+limits+employers'+ability+to+engage+in+disability-related+inquiries,+but+allows+“voluntary+medical+histories”+as+part+of+an+employee+health+program.+(42+U.S.C.+§+12112(d)(4).)+The+Equal+Employment+Opportunity+Commission+(EEOC)+has+suggested+informally+that+the+ADA+would+forbid+a+penalty+in+the+form+of+denial+of+insurance+benefits+to+an+employee+who+declines+to+respond+to+a+health+risk+questionnaire+containing+questions+seeking+disability-related+information.+(Letter+from+Peggy+Mastroianni,+R.,+EEOC+[March+6,+2009],+available+at++[last+visited+June+9,+2011].)+The+implication+is+that+the+EEOC+views+the+provision+of+benefits+as+an+appropriate+baseline,+such+that+a+threat+to+deprive+someone+of+these+benefits+if+they+refuse+to+complete+an+HRA+has+the+potential+to+be+coercive,+rendering+the+medical+history+“involuntary.”>Google Scholar
Bhattacharya, J. Bundorf, M. K., “The Incidence of the Healthcare Costs of Obesity,” Journal of Health Economics 28, no. 3 (2009): 649658.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Id., at 649.Google Scholar
See, e.g., Emanuel, E. J., “Ending Concerns About Undue Influence,” Journal of Law, Medicine & Ethics 32, no. 1 (2004): 100104; Halpern, S. D., “Financial Incentives for Research Participation: Empirical Questions, Available Answers, and the Burden of Further Proof,” American Journal of the Medical Sciences (forthcoming 2011) and; Wertheimer, Miller, , supra note 71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Emanuel also identifies a third concern, exploitation, which refers to “the unfair distributions of goods that arise from an interaction” because of weakness in bargaining power. Id., at 101. Wertheimer further explains that for an exploitative agreement to exist, the content must be “unfair or wrong” in some way, perhaps involving an unfair price, or the exchange of a good that should not be exchanged, or a degrading activity. Wertheimer, A., “Remarks on Coercion and Exploitation,” Denver University Law Review 74, no. 4 (1997): 889906, at 898. To the extent that incentive programs are designed to improve health, exploitation would not seem to be a concern.Google Scholar
See Emanuel, , supra note 81, at 101.Google Scholar
See Wertheimer, Miller, , supra note 71, at 391.Google Scholar
See Halpern, , supra note 80.Google Scholar
Emanuel acknowledges this implication of his framework: “[m]onetary inducements for an ethical, legal, and reasonable activity are deemed ‘due’ no matter how high.” See Emanuel, , supra note 80, at 101.Google Scholar
See Halpern, , supra note 81 (reviewing studies).Google Scholar
Halpern, S. D. Karlawish, J. H. T. Casarett, D. Berlin, J. A. Asch, D. A., “Empirical Assessment of Whether Moderate Payments Are Undue or Unjust Inducements for Participation in Clinical Trials,” Archives of Internal Medicine 154, no. 7 (2004): 801803.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cryder, C. London, A. J. Volpp, K. G. Loewenstein, G., “Informative Inducement: Study Payment as a Signal of Risk,” Social Science and Medicine 70, no. 3 (2010): 455464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
See Wertheimer, Miller, , supra note 71, at 391.Google Scholar
See Wertheimer, , supra note 81, at 896, 899 (“The crucial question, after all, is how certain specific characteristics of proposals and acceptances are related to certain specific moral judgments and not whether we call them coercive or exploitative.”).Google Scholar
See, e.g., Mello and Rosenthal, supra note 64; Jesson, , supra note 41, at 241–292; Rothstein, M. A. Harrell, H. L., “Health Risk Reduction Programs in Employer-Sponsored Health Plans: Part II—Law and Ethics,” Journal of Occupational and Environmental Medicine 51, no. 8 (2009): 951957; Bard, J. S., “Public Health and Privacy Collide: Conflicts Between PPACA's Expansion of Employer Wellness Programs and GINA's Prohibitions Against Requiring Employees to Disclose Their Family Medical History,” Journal of Law, Medicine & Ethics 39, no. 3 (2011): 469–487.Google Scholar
HIPAA of 1996, 110 Stat. 1936, Pub L. 104–191; 26 C.F.R. § 54.9802–1, 29 C.F.R. § 2590.702, 45 C.F.R. § 146.121.Google Scholar
See, e.g., 29 C.F.R. § 2590.702(f).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(2).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(A).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(B).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(C).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(D).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(E).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(A).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(A).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(a) (applying nondiscrimination requirements to a “group health plan and a health insurance issuer offering group or individual health insurance coverage”).Google Scholar
See supra Part III.Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(A).Google Scholar
See ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3) (A).Google Scholar
The Kaiser Family Foundation and Health Research & Educational Trust, Employer Health Benefits 2010, at 1, available at <http://ehbs.kf.org/pdf/2010/8085.pdf> (last visited June 9, 2011).+(last+visited+June+9,+2011).>Google Scholar
Notice of Proposed Rulemaking for Bona Fide Wellness Programs, 66 F.R. 1421 at 1422.Google Scholar
ACA § 4303, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 280I and § 280I-1.Google Scholar
See 29 C.F.R. § 2590.702(b)(2)(i)(B).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(3)(D).Google Scholar
See 29 C.F.R. § 2590.702(d).Google Scholar
ACA § 1201, to be codified at 42 U.S.C. § 300gg-4(j)(1)(A).Google Scholar