Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Easy-Come-Easy-Go: Moral Hazard in the Context of Return to Education

  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This empirical study advances the understanding of the theory of investment in human capital by outlining limitations to its applicability in the context of return to education. The study uses the concept of moral hazard to examine circumstances when financial support for education purpose generates less desirable post-graduation incomes. This study explores the relationship between financial support and post-graduation incomes using data from the Survey of Income and Program Participation that is designed to measure the economic situation of individuals. Results suggest that students are less likely to engage in moral hazardous behavior to the degree to which they are older and to the degree to which they receive costlier financial assistance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Notes

  1. As a reference, in 2001 the median earnings of men who worked full-time year-round were $38,275, while women’s median earnings were $29,215 (DeNavas-Walt and Cleveland 2002).

References

  • Aguinis, H., & Kraiger, K. (2009). Benefits of training and development for individuals and teams, organizations and society. Annual Review of Psychology, 60, 451–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1963). Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. The American Economic Review, 53(5), 941–973.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baron, R. M., & Kenny, D. A. (1986). The moderator-mediator variable distinction in social psychological research: Conceptual, strategic, and statistical considerations. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 51(6), 1173–1182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1962). Investment in human capital: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 70(5), Part 2: Investment in human beings, 9–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1967). Human Capital and the Personal Distribution of Income: An Analytical Approach. W.S. Woytinsky Lecture No. 1. Ann Arbor, MI: Institute of Public Administration, University of Michigan.

  • Blundell, R., Dearden, L., & Sianesi, B. (2005). Evaluating the effect of education on earnings: Models, methods and results from the National Child Development Survey. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A, 168(3), 473–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodvarsson, O. B., & Walker, R. L. (2004). Do parental cash transfers weaken performance in college? Economics of Education Review, 23(5), 483–495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borkovski, S. C., & Ugras, Y. J. (1992). The ethical attitudes of students as a function of age, sex, and experience. Journal of Business Ethics, 11(12), 961–979.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card, D., & Lemieux, T. (2001). Can falling supply explain the rising return to college for younger men? A cohort-based approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 705–746.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casson, M. H, Jr. (2007). Reducing teacher moral hazard in the U.S. elementary and secondary educational system through merit-pay: An application of the principal–agency theory. Forum for Social Economics, 36(2), 87–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chapman, B. (2006). Income contingent loans for higher education: International reforms. In E. A. Hanushek & F. Welch (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of education (Vol. 2, pp. 1435–1503). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cigno, A., & Luporini, A. (2009). Scholarships or student loans? Subsidizing higher education in the presence of moral hazard. Journal of Public Economy, 11, 55–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Darvish-Lecker, T., & Kahana, N. (1990). Study-grant schemes and effort: An economic model. Bulletin of Economic Research, 42(3), 229–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Day, J. C., & Newburger, E. C. (2002). The big payoff: Educational attainment and synthetic estimates of work-life earnings. Suitland, MD: U.S. Census Bureau.

    Google Scholar 

  • Del Rey, E., & Racionero, M. (2010). Financing schemes for higher education. European Journal of Political Economy, 26(1), 104–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeNavas-Walt, C., & Cleveland, R. W. (2002). Money income in the United States: 2001. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Commerce and U.S. Census Bureau.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deumark, D., & Taubman, P. (1995). Why do wage profiles slope upward? Tests of the general human capital model. Journal of Labor Economics, 13(4), 736–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamondand, D. W., & Dybvig, P. H. (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. The Journal of Political Economy, 91(3), 401–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, J. R., & Schurer, L. L. (2007). Methods for integrating moderation and mediation: A general analytical framework using moderated path analysis. Psychological Methods, 12(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansenand, G. D., & Imrohoroglu, A. (1992). The role of unemployment insurance in an economy with liquidity constraints and moral hazard. Journal of Political Economy, 100(1), 118–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hogan, V., & Walker, I. (2007). Education choice under uncertainty: Implications for public policy. Labour Economics, 14(6), 894–912.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • James, L. R., & Brett, J. M. (1984). Mediators, moderators, and tests for mediation. Journal of Applied Psychology, 69(2), 307–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, R. W., & Neumark, D. (1996). Wage decline and older men. Review of Economics and Statistics, 78, 740–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohlberg, L. (1984). Psychology of moral development: The nature and validity of moral stages (Vol. 2). San Francisco: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P. (1976). Age, experience, and wage growth. American Economic Review, 66(4), 548–558.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leigh, A., & Chris, R. (2005). Estimating returns to education: Three natural experiment techniques compared (pp. 1–24). Canberra, ACT: The Australian National University Center for Economic Policy Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathieu, J. E., Tannenbaum, S. I., & Salas, E. (1992). Influences of individual and situational characteristics on measures of training effectiveness. Academy of Management Journal, 35(4), 828–847.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meglino, B. M., & Korsgaard, M. A. (2004). Considering rational self-interest as a disposition: Organizational implications of other orientation. Journal of Applied Psychology, 89(6), 946–959.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, D. T. (1999). The norm of self-interest. American Psychologist, 54(12), 1053–1060.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, P. W., Mulvey, C., & Martin, N. (2006). The return to schooling: Estimates from a sample of young Australian twins. Labour Economics, 13(5), 571–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, experience, and earnings. New York: Columbia University Press for National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muller, D., Judd, C. M., & Yzerbyt, V. Y. (2005). When moderation is mediated and mediation is moderated. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 89(6), 852–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neubam, D. O., Pagell, M., Drexler, J. A., Mckee-Ryan, F. M., & Larson, E. (2009). Business education and its relationship to student personal moral philosophies and attitudes toward profits: An empirical response to critics. Academy of Management Learning and Education, 8(1), 9–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. V. (1974). Overinsurance and public provision of insurance: The roles of moral hazard and adverse selection. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88(1), 44–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M. E. (1991). Towards a dynamic theory of strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 12, 95–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, M. E. (1982). Asymptotic confidence intervals for indirect effects in structural equation models. In S. Leinhart (Ed.), Sociological methodology (pp. 290–312). San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Long, N., & Shimomura, K. (1999). Education, moral hazard, and endogenous growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 23(5–6), 675–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Virginia Commonwealth University. (2012). Title IV refund policy. Retrieved September 25, 2012, from http://www.enrollment.vcu.edu/finaid/docs/Title_IV_Refund_Policy.pdf.

  • Vogel, J. (2007). Institutions and moral hazard in open economies. Journal of International Economics, 71(2), 495–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Willis, R. J., & Rosen, S. (1979). Education and self-selection. Journal of Political Economy, 87(5), S7–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors gratefully acknowledge funding provided by the Washburn School of Business Beatrice Fellowship Fund, which reimbursed costs associated with this research project.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Liviu Florea.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Walker, R.L., Florea, L. Easy-Come-Easy-Go: Moral Hazard in the Context of Return to Education. J Bus Ethics 120, 201–217 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1656-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1656-8

Keywords

Navigation