1 Introduction

There is much empirical evidence of decreasing absolute risk aversion (DARA), the phenomenon of an individual becoming more willing to take risk when their wealth increases by an absolute amount. This evidence comes from both the field (e.g. Hamal and Anderson 1982) and the laboratory (e.g. Levy 1994). A related concept is risk vulnerability (RV) (Gollier and Pratt 1996). This is the phenomenon of an individual becoming less willing to take risk when mean-zero background risk (independent of other risks) is added to their wealth.

Risk vulnerability is an important hypothesis, especially in the light of the 2008 global financial crisis, and the global recession that followed. The period of (and immediately following) the crisis amounted to a textbook example of a period of abnormally high background risk. It is important to understand the impact of this on individuals’ risk attitude in order to gain greater insight into our understanding of the overall impact of the crisis for future reference. It has been shown, for example, that risk-vulnerable agents respond to an increase in background risk by adjusting their portfolio in favour of safe assets and by demanding more insurance (Gollier and Pratt 1996). Risk Vulnerability has even been put forward as an explanation for the well-known equity premium puzzle (Mehra and Prescott 1985; Weil 1992).

In many theoretical studies, RV is assumed. For example, Heaton and Lucas (2000) invoke the assumption in their explanations of portfolio puzzles. However, perhaps surprisingly, there is comparatively little empirical evidence of RV.

Experimental evidence of RV has been found by Beaud and Willinger (2015), Lusk and Coble (2008) and others. In this paper, we instead use survey data drawn from the wider population. It may be argued that in the present context survey data have considerable advantages over experimental data with regard to external validity. Aside from the standard advantages of a larger and more representative sample, it is reasonable to expect that measures of background risk that might be used in the context of survey data (e.g. measures of macroeconomic uncertainty) have greater external validity than the types of background risk typically induced in a laboratory setting.

Guiso and Paiella (2008) find evidence of RV from a cross section sample of Italian individuals, where the chosen measure of background risk is the variance (over time) in per-capita GDP in the individual’s province of residence. West and Worthington (2014) estimate the impact of macroeconomic conditions on risk attitude using an Australian panel data set. Although they do not explicitly refer to background risk and RV, our analysis is similar to theirs in respect of exploiting a panel data set, and introducing time-varying factors.

The panel data we use is the German Socio-Economic Panel (SOEP). This consists of repeated data on a large number of individuals. We focus on two outcome variables. The first is the response to the direct question about willingness to take risks in general. This response is provided on a 0–10 Likert scale (Likert 1932). Hence, the random effects ordered probit model is used for the analysis of this outcome. The second outcome is the response to a hypothetical lottery investment question. An individual’s response to this question may be taken to imply that that individual’s coefficient of absolute risk aversion lies in a particular interval. Consequently, the random effects interval regression model is used for the analysis of this outcome.

In order to test for DARA and RV, we match repeated responses to these risk-related questions in the panel, to observations (from the month immediately preceding the survey date) on the time-varying factors, HDAX and VDAX. HDAX is the German stock market index, which acts as a proxy for wealth, and hence, a test of the impact of HDAX on risk attitude amounts to a test of DARA. VDAX is an established indicator of volatility in the German stock market,Footnote 1 thereby having a direct interpretation as a measure of background risk prevailing in any given time period. Consequently, a test of the impact of VDAX on risk attitude may be interpreted as a test of RV.

In addition to testing for risk vulnerability in the manner described above, we will go a step further by deducing an estimate of the “coefficient of risk vulnerability” (CRV), which will be defined in due course. To our knowledge, this is the first attempt at the empirical quantification of risk vulnerability.

The paper is organized as follows: Sect. 2 describes the data; Sect. 3 discusses the modelling strategies; Sect. 4 reports and discusses the results, and also constructs an estimate of the CRV; and Sect. 5 concludes.

2 The SOEP data set

The German Socio-Economic Panel Survey (SOEP) has been running since 1984 and surveys a cohort of approximately 20,000 households annually, inquiring into lifestyle and economic activities (Frick et al. 2007; Jürgen and Gert 2007).Footnote 2 In 2004, the survey broadened to include the first questions associated with risk attitude.

What we will refer to as the “general risk question” was repeated biennially until 2008 after which it was asked annually, with the last observation considered in the research being in 2012. The “general risk question” is given by:

How do you see yourself?Are you generally a person who is fully prepared to take risks or do you try to avoid taking risks?

Please tick a box on the scale, where 0 means “risk averse” and the value 10 means “fully prepared to take risks”

$$\begin{aligned} \Box \quad \Box \quad \Box \quad \Box \quad \Box \quad \Box \quad \Box \quad \Box \quad \Box \quad \Box \quad \Box \\ \,\,0 \quad \,\,1 \quad 2 \, \quad 3 \,\quad 4\, \quad \,5\, \,\quad 6\,\, \quad 7\, \, \quad \,8 \quad 9 \quad 10 \end{aligned}$$

For the sake of homogeneity, we consider head-of-households only. The resulting sample consists of 11,903 individuals observed an average of 3.68 times each. Histograms of the general risk response for each year separately are presented in Fig. 1. The most interesting feature of these histograms is the changing shape of the distribution of responses between years. In 2004 and 2006, it appears that the distribution is fairly symmetric around the midpoint of 5, roughly implying risk neutrality. In 2008, 2009, and 2010, however, there is a definite sense that the distribution is more concentrated on the lower half, implying a tendency to risk aversion. These years, of course, correspond to the global recession which followed the 2008 global financial crisis. The asymmetry is seen most clearly in 2009, and this is not surprising since 2009 is considered to be the nadir of the crisis. In 2011 and 2012, we see an apparent return to symmetry, and the distribution for 2012 appears surprisingly similar to the pre-crisis distributions seen in 2004 and 2006. Since the impact of the crisis on the response is exactly the sort of effect in which we are most interested, repeated responses over this particular set of years appear ideal for testing the hypothesis of RV.

Data on responses to the general risk question forms the focus of our first model described in Sect. 3.1 below.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Distribution of self-reported risk attitude (household head)

The second question that is of interest to us is the “hypothetical lottery question”. The question takes the following form:

Imagine that you have won €100,000 in the lottery. Immediately after receiving your winnings you receive the following offer: You have the chance to double your money. But it is equally possible that you will lose half the amount invested. You can participate by staking all or part of your €100,000 on the lottery, or choose not to participate at all.What portion of your lottery winnings are you prepared to stake on this financially risky, yet potentially lucrative lottery investment?

  • €100,000 (i.e. all of it);

  • €80,000;

  • €60,000;

  • €40,000;

  • €20,000;

  • Nothing: I would decline the offer

The hypothetical lottery question was asked only twice, in 2004 and in 2009. Histograms of responses for these two years are shown in Fig. 2. Again it is illuminating to compare the histograms between years. In both cases, we see a mode at the choice of a zero investment, implying risk aversion. However, this mode appears much more prominent in 2009 than in 2004, and again it is reasonable to hypothesize that this is a consequence of 2009 coinciding with the nadir of the global recession that followed the financial crisis.

Data on responses to the hypothetical lottery question form the focus of our second model which is described in Sect. 3.2. The Spearman correlation coefficient between the two responses (self-reported risk attitude and investment in hypothetical lottery) is + 0.2596, with a p-value of 0.0000. The implied consistency between the two responses is a useful basis for data validation.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Distribution of response to hypothetical lottery question

From the SOEP data, we also extract a number of demographic variables which are used as explanatory variables in the two models.Footnote 3 These include age, gender, marital status, and years of education. Descriptive statistics of all variables used, along with SOEP dataset codes, are supplied in Table 4 of the Appendix.

As mentioned in Sect. 1, the financial variables we use are the German stock market index (HDAX) and the German stock market volatility index (VDAX).Footnote 4 The former may be considered a suitable proxy for wealth, while the latter is a proxy for the prevailing level of background risk.Footnote 5 In Fig. 3, we present time series plots of these two variables (HDAX, left panel, and VDAX, right panel). The solid sections of the lines represent years in which data on responses to the general risk question are available; the shaded bars represent periods in which the hypothetical lottery question was asked. The most important features of these plots are the steep fall in HDAX and the even steeper rise in VDAX that coincide with the onset of the global financial crisis in 2008.

Fig. 3
figure 3

HDAX, Stock market index (left panel), and VDAX, Stock market volatility (right panel), over time. Source: datastream. Solid sections of the lines represent periods in which data on responses to the general risk question are available; the shaded vertical bars represent the periods in which the hypothetical lottery question was asked

Linking together the observations made from the two time series graphs (Fig. 3) with those from the two histograms of response data (Figs. 1, 2) leads directly to the two testable hypotheses that are the focus of this paper. A positive effect of HDAX on willingness to take risk (or a negative effect on absolute risk aversion) will amount to evidence of DARA. A negative effect of VDAX on willingness to take risk (or a positive effect on absolute risk aversion) will amount to evidence of RV.

3 Modelling strategies

In this section, we shall develop modelling strategies for the responses to the two risk-related survey questions presented and discussed in Sect. 2.

3.1 General risk attitude: model 1

For responses to the general risk question, we shall use the random effects ordered probit model, which is outlined as follows.Footnote 6 Let i index respondent, \(i=1,\ldots ,n\), and let t index time period, \(t=1,\ldots ,T\). Let \(y_{it}\) be respondent i’s response to the general risk question about risk taking in period t, and assume that this can take one of the integer values \(1,2,3,\ldots ,J\). Let \(y^{*}_{it} (-\infty<y^{*}_{it}<+\infty )\) be the underlying latent variable representing respondent i’s propensity to risk taking in period t. Let \(x_{it}\) be a vector of characteristics relevant in explaining the risk attitude of respondent i at time t. Let \(z_{t}\) be a vector of financial variables. The random effects ordered probit model is based on the assumption that \(y^{*}_{it}\) depends linearly on \(x_{it}\) and \(z_{t}\), according to:

$$\begin{aligned}&y^{*}_{it}=x_{it}^\prime \beta +z_{t}^\prime \gamma + u_i+\epsilon _{it} \nonumber \\&u_i\sim N(0,\sigma _u^2), \quad \epsilon _{it}\sim N(0,1)\,\, i=1, \ldots , n,\quad t=1,\ldots T. \end{aligned}$$
(1)

\(\beta \) and \(\gamma \) are vectors of parameters; neither contains an intercept. There are two stochastic terms: the individual-specific term \(u_i\) and the random error term \(\epsilon _{it}\). Note that these are both assumed to be normally distributed with mean zero; the variance of \(u_i\) is a free parameter, while the variance of \(\epsilon _{it}\) is, for identification, normalized to 1. This normalization is required in order to set the otherwise arbitrary scale of the latent variable \(y^*\). The latent variable \(y^*\) is linked to the observed variable y via a set of \(J-1\) cut-point parameters, which are estimated along with the other parameters.

We will be particularly interested in the elements of \(\gamma \). The parameter estimate associated with HDAX (resp. VDAX) will enable us to test DARA (resp. RV).

3.2 The hypothetical lottery question: Model 2

For responses to the hypothetical lottery question, we shall use the random effects interval regression model, which is outlined as follows.Footnote 7

We will assume that each individual has the Constant Absolute Risk Aversion (CARA) utility function:

$$\begin{aligned} U\left( x\right) =1-\exp \left( -rx\right) \quad -\infty<r<\infty ;\quad x>0 \end{aligned}$$
(2)

so that the individual’s coefficient of absolute risk aversion is r. Recall from Sect. 2 that the hypothetical lottery question requires respondents to choose one of six possible “investments” in a particular lottery.Footnote 8 It is easily established using (2) that (assuming expected utility maximization) each of the six possible investment choices implies a range for r, and the limits of these ranges are presented in Table 1.Footnote 9

Table 1 Ranges of coefficient of absolute risk aversion (r) implied by different investment choices in hypothetical lottery question, assuming expected utility maximization

As in Sect. 3.1, let i index respondent, i = 1,\(\ldots ,n\), and let t index time period, \(t=1,\ldots ,T\). For respondent i in period t let \(y_{it}\) be the investment choice and let \(r_{it}\) be the coefficient of absolute risk aversion. Since observations on \(y_{it}\) imply intervals for \(r_{it}\), we model the variable \(r_{it}\) as follows.

$$\begin{aligned} r_{it}= & {} x_{it}^\prime \beta +z_{t}^\prime \gamma +u_{i}+\epsilon _{it}\quad i=1,\ldots ,n;\quad t=1,\ldots ,T\nonumber \\\ \quad u_{i}\,\,\sim & {} \,\,N\left( 0,\sigma ^2_u\right) ; \epsilon _{it}\sim N\left( 0,\sigma ^2_\epsilon \right) \end{aligned}$$
(3)

The relationship between the observed investment choice \(y_{it}\) and the (latent) risk attitude variable \(r_{it}\) is (using the values from Table 1):

$$\begin{aligned} y_{it}= 100,000\Rightarrow & {} \quad -\infty<r_{it}\le 0.50\nonumber \\ y_{it}= 80,000\Rightarrow & {} \quad 0.50<r_{it}\le 0.70\nonumber \\ y_{it}= 60,000\Rightarrow & {} \quad 0.70<r_{it}\le 0.95\nonumber \\ y_{it}= 40,000\Rightarrow & {} \quad \,\,\,0.95<r_{it}\le 1.50\nonumber \\ y_{it}= 20,000\Rightarrow & {} \quad \,\,\,1.50<r_{it}\le 4.70\nonumber \\ y_{it}= 0 \quad\Rightarrow & {} \quad \,\,\,4.70<r_{it}\le \infty \end{aligned}$$
(4)

(3) and (4) together define the random effects interval regression model whose parameters may be estimated using Maximum likelihood.Footnote 10

With reference to (3), the risk attitude for respondent i at time t, \(r_{it}\), depends on the respondent’s characteristics, contained in \(x_{it}\), and also on financial variables as pertaining at time t, contained in \(z_{t}\). Once again, we are interested in the elements of \(\gamma \). In particular, let \(\gamma _v\) be the coefficient associated with the logarithm of our background risk measure, VDAX. If we define the coefficient of risk vulnerability (CRV) to be the absolute change in absolute risk aversion resulting from a doubling of background risk, thenFootnote 11

$$\begin{aligned} \text {CRV}= \gamma _v \log (2) \end{aligned}$$
(5)

An estimate of CRV, defined in (5), will be obtained in the next section.

4 Results

In this section, estimation results are presented and discussed.

4.1 Testing for risk vulnerability using self-reported risk attitude

In Table 2, we present results from the application of the random effects ordered probit model, described in Sect. 3.1, to panel data on self-reported willingness to take (general) risk. Model 1 in Table 2 explains the response purely in terms of demographic characteristics of the individual, and the effect of each of these variables is strongly significant. In particular, we see a greater propensity to take risks by younger, more highly-educated, unmarried, males. These findings are in agreement with previous research using the same data source on the determinants of risk attitude (Dohmen et al. 2011).

Model 2 in Table 2 includes an income/wealth variable in the form of the logarithm of income from asset flows. This variable has a strongly positive effect on the propensity to take risk, and this result is consistent with decreasing absolute risk aversion (DARA).

Model 3 in Table 2 includes the two financial variables log(HDAX)\(_{-1}\) and log(VDAX)\(_{-1}\), respectively, the logarithm of the two indices HDAX and VDAX in the month previous to the month of the interview.Footnote 12 As explained previously, HDAX is included to capture the effect of changes in wealth, while VDAX captures the effect of changes in background risk. The strongly positive coefficient on HDAX therefore amounts to further evidence of DARA. The strongly negative effect of VDAX indicates that individuals are less willing to take risks at times when the stock market is more volatile. Treating stock market volatility as a measure of background risk, this result may be interpreted as strong evidence of risk vulnerability (RV).

Finally, Model 4 includes some additional variables, y and \(y^2\), which represent a year trend and a squared year trend, and year-specific month-trends (i.e. variables that take the value 1 in January, 2 in February, and so on for a specific year) and their square. The inclusion of these variables is motivated by concern that the two variables of central attention, HDAX and VDAX, are by their time series nature, fixed within a month. Consequently, all respondents interviewed in a particular month have the same values for each of these variables. This may be viewed as a version of the classic Moulton problem (1986). The standard solution to this problem is to allow “cluster-specific” effects. Since the clusters in this case are time periods, including year trends and year-specific month-trends allows for the required month effects in a way that also allows for time series structure of the data. Although this causes some coefficients to change in value from Model 3, the key conclusions (in particular strong evidence of RV) do not change.

Table 2 Random effects ordered probit results (cut-points estimates not reported)
Table 3 Random effects interval regression using investment choices in hypothetical lottery

4.2 Testing for risk vulnerability using hypothetical lottery choice

We now turn to the results from estimating Eq. (3) using the random effects interval regression model, as explained in Sect. 3.2. Recall that the underlying latent variable in this model is the respondent’s coefficient of absolute risk aversion. Hence we expect the coefficient estimates in this model to be of opposite signs to the corresponding estimates reported in Table 2 (since the latent variable underlying that model was willingness to take risk).

The results of the random effects interval regression model are reported in Table 3. Again we start with a base specification (Model 1) in which only characteristics of the respondent are included. The signs of each of these effects are consistent with those in Table 2 and with results elsewhere in the literature.

The second specification (Model 2) is one which includes a measure of individual wealth, in the form of the logarithm of income from assets. As expected, this has a strongly negative effect, implying decreasing absolute risk aversion (DARA).

Finally, Model 3 includes the two financial variables log(HDAX)\(_{-1}\) and log(VDAX)\(_{-1}\). Log(HDAX)\(_{-1}\) appears to have a strongly positive effect on risk aversion. This can only be seen as an unexpected result. Given the role of HDAX as a proxy for wealth, decreasing absolute risk aversion leads to the prediction that the coefficient of log(HDAX)\(_{-1}\) in this model will be negative. However, note that the coefficient of asset income is still strongly negative, suggesting that asset income is successfully performing the role of a wealth proxy, while we must look elsewhere for the source of the positive effect of HDAX.Footnote 13

Once again the coefficient of log(VDAX)\(_{-1}\) is consistent with the hypothesis of risk vulnerability: Log(VDAX)\(_{-1}\) has a strongly positive effect on risk aversion. If we apply (5) to the coefficient of + 1.66, we obtain a coefficient of risk vulnerability (CRV) of + 1.15, with a 95% confidence interval of (1.03,1.27).Footnote 14 The point estimate is interpreted as follows. If background risk doubles, as it appeared to do at the onset of the global financial crisis (see Fig. 3, right panel), a typical agent’s coefficient of absolute risk aversion is expected to rise by an amount 1.15.

5 Conclusion

We have used two very different survey questions from the German SOEP to test for risk vulnerability (RV). The first is self-reported risk attitude, and the second is investment choice in a hypothetical lottery. We applied a nonparametric test to establish that the two measures have a positive association in the sample. Analysis of the two outcomes has called for the use of two different econometric models: random effects ordered probit and random effects interval regression. Our chosen measure of background risk is the VDAX, which represents the level of volatility in the German stock market. In both estimations, the effect of this variable is strongly significant with a sign consistent with RV.

Given our objective of testing RV, it has been particularly useful to have used data from a time period (2004–2012) that includes what is now widely recognized to be a period of higher-than-normal background risk, the 2008 global financial crisis.

We have defined a coefficient of risk vulnerability (CRV) that can be estimated empirically, and we are not aware of any previous attempts to quantify RV. Using the hypothetical lottery choice data, we have obtained an estimate of CRV of 1.15. The 95 % confidence interval for CRV of (1.03, 1.27), being far from zero and reasonably narrow, indicates firstly that a typical agent does indeed display RV, and secondly that CRV is being estimated with admirable precision.