Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Corporate Governance Systems Diversity: A Coasian Perspective on Stakeholder Rights

  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine corporate governance diversity within a Coasian framework of stakeholder rights, where the central role of governance is to ensure that necessary firm-specific investments are made. This Coasian perspective on stakeholder theory offers a unifying framework towards a global theory of comparative corporate governance, bridging the gap between economic theories of the firm and stakeholder theory, also offering an economics-based alternative to agency theory that explicitly accounts for stakeholder rights. The Coasian perspective encompasses a diversity of corporate governance systems, but does not imply a unique global corporate governance benchmark. We posit that governance is firm dependent and endogenous conditional on the constraints imposed by a national governance system; consequently, there should be no systematic relationship between governance and firm performance once the national constraints are controlled for. However, the same national corporate governance system constraints confer comparative advantages to firms whose efficient levels of firm-specific investments are favored.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Letza et al. (2004), Clarke (2007) and Aguilera and Jackson (2010) for more detailed descriptions of the various streams of thought on corporate governance.

  2. Another alternative to agency theory is the stewardship theory of management (Davis et al. 1997), which “offers managers a different set of motivations, which could potentially include the interests of all relevant stakeholders” (Preston 1998, p. 9). However, the focus of this theory is management and not stakeholder rights, whereas we aim at the broader governance context and integrating stakeholder theory with an economic theory of the firm.

  3. As noted above, this paper does not directly develop what should be the relevant performance measure(s), although clearly the single metric of shareholder value will be insufficient. However, shifting the focus of corporate governance to that of inducing firm-specific investments by the production team members suggests that the surplus of each such team member needs to be included.

  4. Comparative institutional advantage (Hall and Soskice 2001) refers to the concept that institutions supporting certain activities provide a comparative advantage for firms engaged in those activities.

  5. We assume that the firm-specific component can at least be conceptually isolated for each stakeholder and investment. We do this even though both physical assets and human capital are inseparable bundles of firm-specific and non-firm-specific investments.

  6. The terms surplus and quasi-rents are often used interchangeably (e.g., Zingales 1998). Quasi-rents in general are defined as the “difference between the value of an asset in its first-best use and its value in its next best use” (Castinias and Helfat 1991, p. 161).

  7. “Team production…is production in which (1) several types of resources are used and (2) the product is not a sum of separable outputs of each cooperating resource…[and] (3) not all resources in team production belong to one person” (Alchian and Demsetz 1972, p. 779).

  8. Explicit contracts are written contracts that can be enforced in a court of law. Implicit contracts are tacit agreements. If implicit contracts are self-enforcing (Bull 1987; Klein 1996), it is in both parties’ self-interest to fulfill the implicit contract. “Incentives to adhere to an implicit contract include the potential for sharing future profits that arise from the relationship. In contrast, penalties from violating such agreements can include the loss of future profits from the agreement or damage to one party’s reputation that can impede their ability to contract with others in the future” (Gillan et al. 2009, pp. 1630–1631). Career concerns also provide incentives to adhere to implicit contracts (Tirole 2001).

  9. Whereas the Coasian perspective focuses on the allocation of residual rights of control to ensure firm-specific investments, alternative means of motivating team members to make firm-specific investments may also be used in corporate governance. For example, customs and practices that foster long-term employment relationships also encourage firm-specific investments in human capital (Milgrom and Roberts 1992; Blair 1999). Job ladders, career paths, and seniority rules compensate employees over time for their investments in firm-specific human capital, implicitly protecting their investments (Blair 1999). Corporate culture and norms may foster trust, thereby promoting firm-specific investments in relationships and team building (Blair 1999). Finally, equity ownership by stakeholders such as employees, customers, or suppliers allows for surplus sharing and gives these stakeholders some “voice in governance,” but only as shareholders (Faleye et al. 2006; Zattoni 2011).

  10. In a partnership, a lead partner will need to ensure that firm-specific investments are made by at least another partner, and all the partners participate in some manner in the allocation decision of the ex-post surplus. In a corporation, private or public, governance needs to be designed such that at least two of the primary stakeholders in the firm—providers of capital, management, and employees—make firm-specific investments and thus are team members in the narrow sense defined earlier; as the scope of the corporation expands, other team members such as creditors, suppliers and even customers may have to be incorporated into the governance regime.

  11. Efficiency here refers to the optimal levels of firm-specific investments that can be achieved through the allocation of control rights (and/or other components of a corporate governance system), and not to the levels that can be achieved by a central planner with access to all the relevant information. In this sense, these efficient firm-specific investments are the second-best, constrained by the non-contractibility of firm-specific investments, relative to the first-best that would be achieved through frictionless contracts.

  12. Thus, the Coasian stakeholder theory is consistent with alternative theories of board performance—e.g., resource dependence or stewardship theories (Rashid 2015)—depending on the firm-specific investments that are to be induced.

  13. In our analysis, we consider the most commonly identified team members (sometimes called primary stakeholders) in the literature (e.g., Blair and Stout 1999; Lan and Heracleous 2010).

  14. Davies (2005) characterizes enlightened shareholder value as follows: “The interests of non-shareholder groups thus need to be considered by the directors, but, of course, in this shareholder-centered approach, only to the extent that the protection of those other interests promotes the interests of the shareholders” (cited in Clarke and Klettner 2009, p. 290).

  15. Donaldson and Preston (1995) suggest property rights as a basis for stakeholder theory but, lacking an economic theory of the firm that is consistent with stakeholder rights, limit their arguments to a series of general considerations.

Abbreviations

NGSC:

National governance system constraints

References

  • Adams, R., Hermalin, B., & Weisbach, M. (2010). The role of boards of directors in corporate governance: A conceptual framework and survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1), 58–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aggarwal, R., Erel, I., Stulz, R., & Williamson, R. (2010). Differences in governance practices between U.S. and foreign firms: Measurement, causes and consequences. Review of Financial Studies, 23(3), 3131–3169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguilera, R., & Jackson, G. (2003). The cross-national diversity of corporate governance: Dimensions and determinants. The Academy of Management Review, 28(3), 447–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguilera, R., & Jackson, G. (2010). Comparative and international corporate governance. The Academy of Management Annals, 4(1), 485–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62(5), 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, C., Guay, W., & Weber, J. (2010). The role of information and financial reporting in corporate governance and debt contracting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50, 179–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L. (2005). The case for increasing shareholder power. Harvard Law Review, 118(3), 833–914.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L., Fried, J., & Walker, D. (2002). Managerial power and rent extraction in the design of executive compensation. University of Chicago Law Review, 69, 751–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L., & Roe, M. (1999). A theory of path dependence in corporate ownership and governance. Stanford Law Review, 52(1), 127–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becht, M., Bolton, P., & Roëll, A. (2005). Corporate governance and control. ECGI Working Paper Series in Finance.

  • Bhagat, S., & Black, B. (1999). The uncertain relationship between board composition and firm performance. Business Lawyer, 54(3), 921–963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagat, S., & Bolton, B. (2008). Corporate governance and firm performance. Journal of Corporate Finance, 14, 257–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blair, M. (1999). Firm-specific human capital and theories of the firm. In M. Blair & M. Roe (Eds.), Employees and corporate governance (pp. 58–90). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blair, M., & Stout, L. (1999). A team production theory of corporate law. Virginia Law Review, 85(2), 247–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blair, M., & Stout, L. (2006). Specific investment and corporate law. European Business Organization Law Review, 7, 473–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bull, C. (1987). The existence of self-enforcing implicit contracts. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 147–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bushman, R., & Smith, A. (2003). Transparency, financial accounting information, and corporate governance. FRBNY Economic Policy Review, 9(1), 65–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castinias, R., & Helfat, C. (1991). Managerial resources and rents. Journal of Management, 17(1), 155–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chew, D. H. (1997). Introduction. In D. H. Chew (Ed.), Governance systems. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, T. (2005). Accounting for Enron: shareholder value and stakeholder interests. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 13(5), 598–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, T. (2007). International corporate governance: A comparative approach. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, T. (2013). Deconstructing the mythology of shareholder value: A comment on Lynn Stout’s “The Shareholder Value Myth”. Accounting, Economics and Law—A Convivium, 3(1), 15–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, T., & Klettner, A. (2009). Implementing corporate social responsibility: A creative tension between regulation and corporate initiatives? In D. Crowther & G. Aras (Eds.), Global perspectives on corporate governance and CSR (pp. 269–312). Aldershot/Farnham: Gower Publishing/Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coff, R. W. (1999). When competitive advantage doesn’t lead to performance: The resource-based view and stakeholder bargaining power. Organization Science, 10(2), 119–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costinot, A. (2009). On the origins of comparative advantage. Journal of International Economics, 77(2), 255–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies, P. (2005) Enlightened shareholder value and the new responsibilities. W.E. Hearn Lecture at the University of Melbourne Law School, October 4.

  • Davis, J. H., Schoorman, F. D., & Donaldson, L. (1997). Towards a stewardship theory of management. The Academy of Management Review, 22(1), 20–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denis, D., & McConnell, J. (2003). International corporate governance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 38(1), 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dilger, A. (2002). Ökonomik betrieblicher Mitbestimmung: die wirtschaftlichen Folgen von Betriebsräten. München: Hampp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, T., & Preston, L. (1995). The stakeholder theory of the corporation: Concepts, evidence and implications. Academy of Management Review, 20(1), 65–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • du Plessis, J., & Saenger, I. (2012). An overview of the corporate governance debate in Germany. In J. du Plessis, B. Groβfled, C. Luttermann, I. Saenger, O. Sandrock, & M. Casper (Eds.), German corporate governance in international and European context (2nd ed., pp. 15–54). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Faleye, O., Mehrotra, V., & Morck, R. (2006). When labor has a voice in corporate governance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 41(3), 489–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. (1980). Agency problems and the theory of the firm. The Journal of Political Economy, 88(2), 288–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fauver, L., & Fuerst, M. E. (2006). Does good corporate governance include employee representation? Evidence from German corporate boards. Journal of Financial Economics, 82(3), 673–710.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, E. (1984). Strategic management: A stakeholder approach. Boston: Pittman Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, R. E., Wicks, A., & Parmar, B. (2004). Stakeholder theory and “The corporate objective revisited”. Organization Science, 15(3), 364–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1970, September 13). The social responsibility of business is to increase its profits. New York Times Magazine. Retrieved January 10, 2015, from http://graphics8.nytimes.com/packages/pdf/business/miltonfriedman1970.pdf.

  • Gillan, S., Hartzell, J., & Parrino, R. (2009). Explicit versus implicit contracts: Evidence from CEO employment agreements. Journal of Finance, 64(4), 1629–1655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ginglinger, E., Megginson, W., & Waxin, T. (2011). Employee ownership, board representation, and corporate financial policies. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17, 868–887.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goergen, M., Manjon, M. C., & Rennboog, L. (2008). Recent developments in German corporate governance. International Review of Law and Economics, 28(3), 175–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gompers, P. A., Ishii, J. L., & Metrick, A. (2003). Corporate governance and equity prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 107–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, J. N. (2003). An international relations perspective on the convergence of corporate governance: German shareholder capitalism and the European Union, 1990–2000. European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI)—Finance Research Paper Series; ECGI—Law Working Paper No. 06/2003; Harvard Law and Economics Discussion Paper No. 406.

  • Grossman, S., & Hart, O. (1986). The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P., & Soskice, D. (2001). Varieties of capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann, H., & Kraakman, R. (2001). The end of history for corporate law. Georgetown Law Journal, 89(2), 439–468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann, H., & Kraakman, R. (2004). Agency problems and legal strategies. In R. Kraakman, P. Davies, H. Hansmann, G. Hertig, K. Hopt, H. Kanda, & E. Rock (Eds.), The anatomy of corporate law: A comparative and functional approach (pp. 21–31). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O. (2008). Economica Coase lecture: Reference points and the theory of the firm. Economica, 75(299), 404–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O., & Moore, J. (1990). Property rights and the nature of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 1119–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hermalin, B., & Weisbach, M. (2003). Boards of directors as an endogenously determined institution: A survey of the economic literature. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, 9(1), 7–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill, C., & Jones, T. (1992). Stakeholder-agency theory. Journal of Management Studies, 29(2), 131–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. The Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 324–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, G. (2005). Stakeholders under pressure: Corporate governance and labour management in Germany and Japan. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 13(3), 419–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, G., & Deeg, R. (2008). Comparing capitalisms: Understanding institutional diversity and its implications for international business. Journal of International Business Studies, 39, 540–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, G., & Moerke, A. (2005). Continuity and change in corporate governance: Comparing Germany and Japan. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 13(3), 351–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. (2002). Value maximization, stakeholder theory, and the corporate objective function. Business Ethics Quarterly, 12(2), 235–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1979). Rights and production functions: An application to labor-managed firms and codetermination. Journal of Business, 52(4), 469–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B. (1996). Why hold-ups occur: The self-enforcing range of contractual relationships. Economic Inquiry, 34, 444–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B., Crawford, R., & Alchian, A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting. Journal of Law and Economics, 21(2), 297–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kochan, T., & Rubinstein, S. (2000). Toward a stakeholder theory of the firm: The Saturn partnership. Organization Science, 11(4), 367–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lan, L. L., & Heracleous, L. (2010). Rethinking agency theory: The view from law. Academy of Management Review, 35(2), 294–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • Letza, S., Sun, X., & Kirkbride, J. (2004). Shareholding versus stakeholding: A critical review of corporate governance. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 12(3), 242–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, R., Feils, D., & Scholnick, B. (2011). Why are different services outsourced to different countries? Journal of International Business Studies, 42(4), 558–571.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michalos, A. C. (1995). A pragmatic approach to business ethics. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1992). Economics, organization & management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morck, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1988). Management ownership and market valuation. Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 293–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mudambi, R., & Nicosia, C. (1998). Ownership structure and firm performance: Evidence from the UK financial services industry. Applied Financial Economics, 8, 175–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müller, H., & Wärneryd, K. (2001). Inside vs. outside ownership: A political theory of the firm. RAND Journal of Economics, 32(3), 527–541.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordberg, D. (2011). Corporate governance: Principles and issues. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunn, N. (2007). Relationship-specificity, incomplete contracts and the pattern of trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 569–600.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Preston, L. E. (1998). Agents, stewards, and stakeholders. The Academy of Management Review, 23(1), 9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rahman, M. (2009). Corporate governance in the European Union: Firm nationality and the ‘German’ model. Multinational Business Review, 17, 77–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rashid, A. (2015). Revisiting agency theory: Evidence of board independence and agency cost from Bangladesh. Journal of Business Ethics, 130, 181–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renaud, S. (2007). Dynamic efficiency of supervisory board codetermination in Germany. Labour, 21(4/5), 689–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, J., & Van den Steen, E. (2000). Shareholder interests, human capital investment and corporate governance. Research Paper No. 1631. Stanford, CA: Graduate School of Business, Stanford University.

  • Roberts, J., & van den Steen, E. (2001). Human capital and corporate governance. In J. Schwalbach (Ed.), Corporate governance (pp. 128–144). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rubach, M., & Sebora, T. (1998). Comparative corporate governance: Competitive implications of an emerging convergence. Journal of World Business, 33(2), 167–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 52(2), 737–783.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stout, L. (2012). The shareholder value myth. San Francisco: Berrett-Koehler Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tang, H. (2012). Labor market institutions, firm-specific skills, and trade patterns. Journal of International Economics, 87(2), 337–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (2001). Corporate governance. Econometrica, 69(1), 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, H., He, J., & Mahoney, J. (2009). Firm-specific knowledge resources and competitive advantage: The roles of economic and relationship-based employee governance mechanisms. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 1265–1285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wessels, R., & Wansbeek, T. (2013). What is the relation (if any) between a firm’s corporate governance arrangements and its financial performance? Working Paper.

  • Williamson, O. (1979). Transaction cost economics: The governance of contractual relations. Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 233–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1984). Corporate governance. Yale Law Journal, 93, 1197–1230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wintoki, M., Linck, J., & Netter, J. (2012). Endogeneity and the dynamics of internal corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics, 105(3), 581–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zattoni, A. (2011). Who should control a corporation? Toward a contingency stakeholder model for allocating ownership rights. Journal of Business Ethics, 103, 255–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zingales, L. (1998). Corporate governance. In P. Newman (Ed.), New Palgrave dictionary of economics and law (Vol. 1, pp. 497–503). London: Macmillan Reference Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zingales, L. (2000). In search of new foundations. Journal of Finance, 55(4), 1623–1653.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Vic Anand, Francesco Bova, Peter Jaskiewicz, David Pyke, Emilson Silva, and participants at the European International Business Academy meeting 2012 and the Academy of International Business meeting 2014 for their comments and feedback. We thank the Social Sciences Research Council of Canada for financial support.

Funding

This study was funded by an insight grant from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dorothee Feils.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Feils, D., Rahman, M. & Şabac, F. Corporate Governance Systems Diversity: A Coasian Perspective on Stakeholder Rights. J Bus Ethics 150, 451–466 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-016-3188-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-016-3188-5

Keywords

Navigation