Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter June 13, 2017

The Iniquity of Money-Metric Poverty in India

  • D Jayaraj EMAIL logo and S Subramanian
From the journal Basic Income Studies

Abstract

This paper is concerned to make three points about money-metric poverty in India: first, that the standard poverty-line approach to measuring poverty considerably underestimates poverty, and that the particular protocols by which India’s official poverty lines are determined are arbitrary and misleading; second, that a view of poverty in which the achievement of a satisfactory level of income is seen as a valuable end in itself, and which is captured in something like Kaushik Basu’s ‘quintile income statistic’, suggests a high order of income-poverty in the country which belies the relatively encouraging trends exhibited by headcount ratios based on official poverty lines; and third, that the continued co-existence of large amounts of poverty with large amounts of inequality needs to be redeemed by some deliberate redistributive strategy aimed at providing something like a guaranteed basic minimum income to every citizen of the country—for reasons, at least, of self-interest, if not justice.

JEL Classification: B40; D30; D31; D63; I32; O15.

Acknowledgements

We are sincerely grateful to two anonymous referees and the Editor of this journal for their detailed comments and suggestions on earlier versions of this paper. The usual caveat applies.

Appendix

A Does first order stochastic dominance necessarily imply an unambiguous reduction in poverty?

If invariance of the poverty standard is sought in the space of ‘real incomes’, then a property of cumulative distribution functions (CDFs) called ‘stochastic dominance’ furnishes a useful guide to the unambiguous poverty ranking of income distributions in terms of the headcount ratio (see Foster & Shorrocks, 1988). A cumulative distribution function is simply a plot of the cumulative proportion of the population with incomes below a given level, for every level of income in the distribution under review. Clearly, the CDF is an increasing (or at least non-decreasing) function of income: the ordinate corresponding to zero income would be zero (that is, zero percent of the population has income less than zero), and the ordinate corresponding to the highest income in the distribution is unity (that is, one hundred percent of the population would have incomes less than the highest income in the distribution). One distribution will be said to first-order stochastically dominate another, if the first distribution lies somewhere below and nowhere above the second distribution. And if this happens, then no matter what poverty line we choose, the headcount ratio for the first distribution will be somewhere lower and never higher than for the second distribution. Under these circumstances, we could say that poverty, as measured by the headcount ratio, is unambiguously lower for the first distribution than for the second.

As a broad rule, one can take it as something of an empirical regularity in the Indian setting, that the distribution of consumption expenditure tends to first-order stochastically dominate an earlier time-period’s distribution as we move forward in time. Secondly, and as we have seen in the text, a ‘calorie drift’ such as is observed in India implies, equivalently, that the (real) poverty line might be expected, over time, to lie further and further above the officially determined poverty line. These two contingencies are captured in Figure 1, which displays the (hypothetical) cumulative distribution functions of consumption expenditure in two successive years, of which the first year is the officially designated ‘reference’ or ‘base’ year, and z1 and z2 are the presumed (real) poverty lines in year 1 and year 2 respectively: in keeping with the stylized facts we have just reviewed, the year 2 cumulative expenditure distribution function has been portrayed as first-order stochastically dominating the year 1 function, and z2 has been taken to be greater than z1.

The official approach to determining the poverty line obliges us to treat z1 as the poverty line for both years 1 and 2: this is compatible with an inter-temporal decline in the headcount ratio of poverty fromH1toH2 in Figure 1, and captures, in essence, the official story of steadily declining money-metric poverty. A question which immediately arises is: is there any reason for treating the pattern of consumption expenditure in year 1 as somehow normatively privileged, for us to treat year 1 as the reference year? The answer, clearly, is ‘no’. This then leaves us open to designating year 2 as the reference year, with an order of arbitrariness which is neither more nor less than the order that presided over the earlier designation of year 1 as the reference year. In such an event, the poverty line would have to be taken to be z2, and we would have to conclude from Figure 1 that poverty has declined fromH1in year 1 toH2in year 2. Neither the magnitudes of the headcount ratios, nor the precise rate of decline in the ratio, are the same when year 2 is the reference year as when year 1 is the reference year, although no matter whether we employ z1 or z2 as the poverty line, we observe a decline in poverty in year 2 vis-à-vis year 1 (the usual ‘stochastic dominance’ argument).

Figure 1: Headcount ratios of poverty for alternative poverty lines.Note: Figure here 1 is the same as Figure 1 in Subramanian (2014).
Figure 1:

Headcount ratios of poverty for alternative poverty lines.

Note: Figure here 1 is the same as Figure 1 in Subramanian (2014).

But what now if each of the two years were to be treated as a ‘reference year’, so that z1 is taken to be the poverty line valid for year 1, and z2 as the poverty line valid for year 2? This, in fact, is the procedure that would be normally compatible with the Food Energy Intake method of determining the poverty line, and the one which Utsa Patnaik (2004, 2007) insists on. In such an event, Figure 1 assures us that we would have to conclude that in transiting from year 1 to year 2, the headcount ratio has actually increased fromH1toH2.

We thus see that a number of inferences are available to us on what has happened to poverty over time, and in the absence of any reasonable criterion which will enable us to privilege any one inference over any of the other inferences, we are left in an indeterminate limbo of widely differing and equally (im)plausible logical outcomes. This surely cannot be a reasonable approach to measuring poverty! And this conclusion emerges from taking seriously the notion that if the poverty line in income terms is a means to the end of escaping deprivation in functionings space, then one should allow for the possibility of a poverty standard which is absolute in the space of functionings while being variable in the space of real incomes.

B What understated poverty lines can obscure

What constitutes the necessary means of subsistence in any society at any time is, as Marx observed in Capital, a matter that is always ‘practically known’. It is such practical knowledge that led the National Commission for Enterprises in the Unorganized Sector (Government of India, 2009) to suggest a pragmatic order of magnitude for the poverty line in India of Rs. 20 per person per day, or Rs. 600 per person per month, for 2004–05. With this poverty line (which many would argue is itself a very modest figure), one finds that the poverty line exceeds the rural average per capita consumption expenditure (as reflected in the relevant National Sample Survey data) of Rs. 564 per person per month in 2004–05. What is the implication of a poverty line which exceeds the average income?

A situation in which the mean income of the reference society is less than the poverty line is one that is not often explicitly encountered in the measurement literature (though for important exceptions, the reader is referred to Lewis & Ulph, 1988; Vaughan, 1987). The problem has been considered earlier by one of the present authors (Subramanian, 1989, 2003). He shows that if H is the proportion of the population in poverty (the head-count ratio), μ is the average income of the distribution under consideration, and z is the poverty line, then, in a situation in which μ<z, it will be the case that the minimum attainable value of the headcount ratio—call it H—will be given by the following expression:

(1)H*=1μ/z.

Briefly, the ‘man overboard’ solution to the utilitarian’s ‘life-boat ethics dilemma’ consists in requiring that a proportion H(1μ/z) of the population be effectively ‘thrown overboard’ from the‘life-boat’: by assigning an income of zero to each of nH persons, one ensures that the headcount ratio of poverty is minimized (here n is the size of the total population). Since people presumably cannot survive without any resources whatever, the requirement, by implication, is to simply allow nH individuals to perish in the cause of minimizing the headcount measure. H may, with justice, be called the ‘triage headcount ratio’: according to the Mirriam-Webster Dictionary (also cited in Jayaraj & Subramanian, 1999; Subramanian, 2003), triage is ‘the sorting of and allocation of treatment to patients and especially battle and disaster victims according to a system of priorities designed to maximize the number of survivors.’ The ‘triage headcount ratio’ H brings into relief the fact that the protocols of conventional poverty measurement are informed by a perverse morality which dictates mortality as a solution to poverty—a theme that has been addressed most notably in the work of Kanbur and Mukherji (2007). This solution, indeed, is what Koopmans (1957) has referred to as the ‘hardboiled’ solution to the ‘survival problem’ in General Equilibrium analysis. When sufficiently under-stated, poverty lines can point in the direction of the‘hardboiled solution’, a fact that is obscured unless it is explicitly brought into relief.

If we accept a poverty line of Rs. 20 per person per day, then in terms of eq.(1), the ‘triage headcount ratio’ H for rural India in 2004–05 works out to 5.88 %. This is another way of saying, given India’s 2004–05 rural population, that if only some 46 million villagers in the country had obligingly curled up and died, rural poverty in the country might have been avoided. (Quantitatively, this would be like wiping Spain, with a population of 43 million, off the global map in 2004–05.)

References

Arun Kumar, (2016). Estimation of the size of the black economy in India, 1996–2012. Economic and Political Weekly, 51(48), 36–42.Search in Google Scholar

Atkinson, A. B (2014). In Inequality: What can be done?. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Atkinson, A. B. (2016). Monitoring global poverty: Report of the commission on global poverty.World Bank Group: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank.http://documents.banquemondiale.org/curated/fr/353781479304286720/pdf/110040-REVISED-PUBLIC.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Bahri, Charu (2016). Farmers are tax exempt, so is company with Rs 215 crore profit. Business Standard,. http://www.business-standard.com/article/specials/farmers-are-tax-exempt-so-is-company-with-rs-215-cr-profit-116031200292_1.html.Search in Google Scholar

Banerjee, A. (2016). Universal basic income: The best way to welfare. http://www.ideasforindia.in/article.aspx?article_id=1695.Search in Google Scholar

Bardhan, P. (2016). Basic income in a poor country. http://www.ideasforindia.in/article.aspx?article_id=1694.Search in Google Scholar

Basu, K. (2001). On the goals of development. G. M. Meier & J. E. Stiglitz (Eds.) In Frontiers of development economics: The future in perspective. New York: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Basu, K. (2006). Globalization, poverty, and inequality: What is the relationship? What can be done? World Development, 34(8), 1361–1373.10.1057/9780230625501_12Search in Google Scholar

Basu, K. (2013). Shared prosperity and the mitigation of poverty: In practice and in precept.World Bank Research Working Paper 670.World Bank Washington, D. C.10.1596/1813-9450-6700Search in Google Scholar

Besley, T (1990). Means testing versus universal provision in poverty alleviation programmes. Economica, 57(225), 119–129.10.2307/2554085Search in Google Scholar

Besley, T. & Kanbur, R. (1990). The principles of targeting. Policy, research, and external affairs., The World Bank, D. C. doi:Working Papers, Office of the Vice President. Development Economics, WPS 385.Search in Google Scholar

Burchardt, T (2013). Should measures of subjective wellbeing inform policy priorities? Editorial. Journal of Poverty and Social Justice, 21(1), 3–5. https://doi.org/10.1332/175982713X664010.https://doi.org/10.1332/175982713X664010Search in Google Scholar

Chaudhuri, A. R. & Somanathan, E. (2011). Impact of biometric identification-based transfers. Economic and Political Weekly, XLVI(21), 77–80.Search in Google Scholar

Davala, S., Jhabvala, R., Mehta, S. K. & Standing, G. (2015). In Basic income: A transformative policy for India. London and New York: Bloomsbury Academic.10.5040/9781472593061Search in Google Scholar

Dreze, J. (2017). Decoding universal basic income for India. http://www.ideasforindia.in/article.aspx?article_id=1763.Search in Google Scholar

Dutta, B. & Panda, M. (2014). Social welfare and household consumption expenditure in India—2004–05 to 2011–12. Economic and Political Weekly, 49(31), 113–122.Search in Google Scholar

Galbraith, J. K. (1999). The unfinished business of the century. http://www.lse.ac.uk/PublicEvents/pdf/20030416t1006z001.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Foster, J. E. & Shorrocks, A. F. (1988). Poverty Orderings. Econometrica, 56(1), 173–177.10.2307/1911846Search in Google Scholar

Ghatak, M. (2016). Is India ready for a universal basic income scheme? http://www.ideasforindia.in/article.aspx?article_id=1696.Search in Google Scholar

Groot, L. F. M. & Peters, H. M. M. (1997). A model of conditional and unconditional social security in an efficiency wage economy: The economic sustainability of a basic income. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Summer 1997, 19(4), 573–597.10.1080/01603477.1997.11490129Search in Google Scholar

Government of India. (2009). In Report on conditions of work and promotion of livelihoods in the unorganized sector. New Delhi: National Commission for Enterprises in the Unorganized Sector.Search in Google Scholar

Government of India. (2017). Economic survey 2016–17 Ministry of Finance, Department of Economic Affairs, Economic Division. http://indiabudget.gov.in/es2016-17/echapter.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Haagh, L (2007). Basic income, occupational freedom and anti-poverty policy. Basic Income Studies, 2(1), 1–6.10.2202/1932-0183.1065Search in Google Scholar

Haagh, L (2011). Working life, well-being and welfare reform: Motivation and institutions revisited. World Development, 39(3), 450–573.10.1016/j.worlddev.2010.08.014Search in Google Scholar

Haagh, L. (2013). Citizen’s income and democratization in Latin America – A multi-institutional perspective. R. Lo Vulo (Ed.) In Citizen’s income and welfare regimes in Latin America: From cash transfers to rights(pp. 211-232). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Search in Google Scholar

Haagh, L. (2017a). Basic income’s radical role. Social Europe Website. https://www.socialeurope.eu/2017/03/basic-incomes-radical-role/.Search in Google Scholar

Haagh, L. (2017b). Basic income should be seen as a democratic right: We should consider basic income a democratic right rather than a solution to unemployment. https://medium.com/rsa-journal/basic-income-should-be-seen-as-a-democratic-right-b249ab6078b0(First Published in Royal Society of Arts Journal, Issue 4, 2016–17).Search in Google Scholar

Hassan, A. (2016). Basic income: A comparative study of Brazil and India. Lund University 2016, NEKH01. http://lup.lub.lu.se/luur/download?func=downloadFile&recordOId=8603235&fileOId=8603245.Search in Google Scholar

Jayaraj, D. & Subramanian, S (1999). Poverty and discrimination: Measurement, and evidence from Rural India. B. Harriss-White & S. Subramanian (Eds.) In Illfare in India: Essays on India’s social sector in Honour of S. Guhan. New Delhi: Sage Publishers.Search in Google Scholar

Jayaraj, D. & Subramanian, S (2012). On the interpersonal inclusiveness of India’s consumption expenditure growth. Economic and Political Weekly, XLVII(45), 56–66.Search in Google Scholar

Jayaraj, D. & Subramanian, S (2013). On the inter-group inclusiveness of India’s consumption expenditure growth. Economic and Political Weekly, XLVIII(10), 65–70.Search in Google Scholar

Joshi, V. (2016). Universal basic income for india. http://www.ideasforindia.in/article.aspx?article_id=1708.Search in Google Scholar

Kadekodi, G. & Kulkarni, K (2006). Status of health and medical care in India: A macro perspective. Indian Institute of Public Administration, Centre for Multi-Disciplinary Development Research (CMDR), and United Nations Development Programme (UNDP), NDP, India. http://iipa.org.in/common/pdf/PAPER%205_STATUS%20OF%20HEALTH.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Kanbur, S. R. & Mukherjee, D. (2007). Premature mortality and poverty measurement. Bulletin of Economic Research, 19(4), 339–359.10.1111/j.0307-3378.2007.00265.xSearch in Google Scholar

Kapur, D., Mukhopadhyay, P. & Subramanian, A. (2008). The case for direct cash transfers to the poor. Economic and Political Weekly, 43(15), 37–43.Search in Google Scholar

Koopmans, T. C. (1957). In Three essays on the state of economic science. New York: McGraw-Hill 2.Search in Google Scholar

Kotwal, A., Murugkar, M. & Ramaswami, B. (2011). PDS forever? Economic and Political Weekly, XLVI(21), 72–76.Search in Google Scholar

Kotwal, A., Ramaswami, B. & Wadhwa, W. (2011). Economic liberalization and Indian economic growth: What’s the evidence? Journal of Economic Literature, 49(4), 1152–1199.10.1257/jel.49.4.1152Search in Google Scholar

Lavallee, E., Olivier, A., Pasquier-Doumer, L. & Robilliard, A.-S. (2010). Poverty alleviation policy targeting: A review of experience in developing countries. DT/2010-10, Dauphine Universite Paris and IRD, Institut de Recherche Pour le Developpement, Paris.Search in Google Scholar

Lavinas, L. (2013). Brazil: The lost road to citizen’s income. R. Lo Vulo (Ed.) In Citizen’s income and welfare regimes in Latin America: From cash transfers to rights. New York: Palgrave Macmillan (pp. 29-49).Search in Google Scholar

Lewis, G. W. & Ulph, D. T. (1988). Poverty, inequality and welfare. The Economic Journal, 98(390), 117–131.10.2307/2233309Search in Google Scholar

Malul, M., Gal, J. & Greenstein, M. (2009). A universal basic income: Theory and practice in the Israeli case. Basic Income Studies, 4(1), 1–19.10.2202/1932-0183.1123Search in Google Scholar

Manwu, H. J. (2015). The rise and fall of the basic income grant campaign: Lessons from Namibia. Global Labour Journal, 6(3), 336–350.Search in Google Scholar

Mkandawire, T. (2005). Targeting and universalism in poverty reduction. Social Policy and Development, Programme Paper Number 23, United Nations Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD), Palais des Nations,1211 Geneva 10, Switzerland.Search in Google Scholar

Moatsos, M. (2015). Global absolute poverty: Behind the veil of dollarsCenter for Global Economic History Working Paper Series 77, CGEH, Utrecht Universitythe Netherlands[Forthcoming in: Journal of Globalization and Development].10.1515/jgd-2016-0033Search in Google Scholar

Moene, K. O. & Ray, D. (2016). The universal basic share and social incentives. http://www.ideasforindia.in/article.aspx?article_id=1698.Search in Google Scholar

Mulvale, P. (2008). Basic income and the Canadian welfare state: Exploring the realms of possibility. Basic Income Studies, 3(1), 1–26. Article 6. doi:10.2202/1932-0183.1084.Search in Google Scholar

Narayanan, S. (2011). A case for reframing the cash transfer debate in India. Economic and Political Weekly, XLVI(21), 41–48.Search in Google Scholar

Painter, A (2016). Pragmatism, idealism and basic income: A transformative investment in human potential. Juncture, 22(4), 289–292.10.1111/j.2050-5876.2016.00876.xSearch in Google Scholar

Parijs, P. V. (n.d). Boston Review: A Political and Literary Forum A basic income for all. http://bostonreview.net/archives/BR25.5/vanparijs.html.Search in Google Scholar

Parijs, P. V. (2005). Basic income: A simple and powerful idea for the twenty-first century. Prepublication Versionhttps://www.uclouvain.be/cps/ucl/doc/etes/documents/Chap1.Simple_and_Powerful.pdf.10.1177/0032329203261095Search in Google Scholar

Parikh, K. S. (2013). Right to food and foodgrain policy. Economic and Political Weekly, XLVIII(11), 23–27.Search in Google Scholar

Patnaik, U. (2004). The Republic of Hunger. Social Scientist, 32(9–10), 9–35. [Text of a Public Lecture on the occasion of the 50th Birthday of Safdar Hashmi on April 10, 2004, New Delhi].10.2307/3518206Search in Google Scholar

Patnaik, U. (2007). Neoliberalism and rural poverty in India. Economic and Political Weekly, 48(32), 3132–3150.Search in Google Scholar

Planning Commission. (1993). In Report of the expert group on estimation of proportion and number of poor. New Delhi: Government of India.Search in Google Scholar

Planning Commission. (2009). In Report of the expert group to review the methodology for estimation of poverty. New Delhi: Government of India.Search in Google Scholar

Planning Commission. (2014). In Report of the expert group to review the methodology for measurement of poverty. New Delhi: Government of India.Search in Google Scholar

Ray, D. (2016). The universal basic share. www.ideasforindia.in/article.aspx?article_id=1697.Search in Google Scholar

Reddy, S. & Pogge, T. (2010). How not to count the poor. S. Anand, P. Segal & J. Stiglitz (Eds.) In Debates on the measurement of global poverty. New York: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Reed, H. & Lansley, S. (2016). Universal basic income: An idea whose time has come? A Publication by Compass. https://www.compassonline.org.uk/wp-content/uploads/2016/05/UniversalBasicIncomeByCompass-Spreads.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Sen, A. (2001). Consumer expenditure, distribution and poverty: Implications of the NSS 55th round. Macroscan: An Alternative Economics Webcentre. http://www.macroscan.org/anl/jan01/Abhijit_Sen.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Sen, A. (1983). Poor, relatively speaking. Oxford Economic Papers, 35(2), 153–169.10.1093/oxfordjournals.oep.a041587Search in Google Scholar

Sen, A. (1985). In Commodities and capabilities. North-Holland: Amsterdam.Search in Google Scholar

Srinivasan, T. N. (2016). Minimum standard of living for all Indians: Perspective. http://www.ideasforindia.in/article.aspx?article_id=1699.Search in Google Scholar

Standing, G (2008). How cash transfers promote the case for basic income. Basic Income Studies, 3(1), 1–30.10.2202/1932-0183.1106Search in Google Scholar

Standing, G. (2013). India’s experiment in basic income grants. Global Dialogue, 3(5). http://isa-global-dialogue.net/indias-great-experiment-the-transformative-potential-of-basic-income-grants/.Search in Google Scholar

Standing, G. (2014). From cash transfers to basic income: An unfolding Indian Agenda. The Indian Journal of Labour Economics, 57(1), 111–137.Search in Google Scholar

Standing, G. (2016). Cash transfers can work better than subsidies. The Hindu. December 6, 2014.Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. (1989). Poverty-minimization in the light of ‘Life-Boat Ethics’. Journal of Quantitative Economics, 4, 239–249.Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. (2003). Aspects of global deprivation and disparity: A child’s guide to some simple-minded arithmetic. F. Carlucci & F. Marzano (Eds.) In Poverty, growth and welfare in the world economy in the 21st century. Bern: Peter Lang.Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. (2011). The poverty line: Getting it wrong again. Economic and Political Weekly, 46(48), 37–42.Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. (2014). The poverty line: Getting it wrong again … and again. Economic and Political Weekly, 49(47), 66–70.Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. (2015). Once more unto the breach … the world bank’s latest‘Assault’ on global poverty. Economic and Political Weekly, 50(45), 35–40.Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. & Jayaraj, D. (2012). On the interpersonal inclusiveness of India’s consumption growth. Economic and Political Weekly, XLVII(45), 56–66.Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. & Jayaraj, D. (2013a). Economic inequality in India: Value-neutral measurement? Challenge: The Magazine of Economic Affairs, 56(4), 26–37.10.2753/0577-5132560403Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. & Jayaraj, D. (2013b). The evolution of consumption and wealth inequality in India: A quantitative assessment. Journal Of Globalization and Development, 4(2), 253–281.10.1515/jgd-2013-0018Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. & Jayaraj, D. (2015a). Growth and inequality in the distribution of India’s consumption expenditure. Economic and Political Weekly, 50(32), 39–47.Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. & Jayaraj, D. (2015b). A very simple money-metric welfare indicator for India based on the quintile income statistic. Journal of Quantitative Economics, 13(2), 305–312. doi:10.1007/s40953-015-0011-6.Search in Google Scholar

Subramanian, S. & Jayaraj, D. (2016). The quintile income statistic, money-metric poverty, and disequalizing growth in India: 1983 to 2011–12. Economic and Political Weekly, 51(5), 73–79.Search in Google Scholar

Suplicy, E. M. (2006). Citizen’s basic income: The answer is blowing in wind. http://www.usbig.net/papers/152-Suplicy-blowin.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Svedberg, P. (2012). Reforming or replacing the public distribution system with cash transfers? Economic and Political Weekly, XLVII(7), 53–62.Search in Google Scholar

Tobin, J. (1966). The case for an income guarantee. The Public Interest, 4(Summer 1966), 31–41.Search in Google Scholar

Vaughan, R. N. (1987). Welfare approaches to the measurement of poverty. The Economic Journal, 97(Conference 1987), 160–170.10.2307/3038237Search in Google Scholar

Vuolo, R. L. (2013). Introduction. R. Lo Vulo (Ed.) In Citizen’s income and welfare regimes in Latin America: From cash transfers to rights. New York:Palgrave Macmillan (pp. 126).10.1057/9781137077547Search in Google Scholar

Wispelaere, J. D. & Stirton, L. (2011). The administrative efficiency of basic income. Policy & Politics, 39(1), 115–132.10.1332/030557311X546352Search in Google Scholar

World Bank. (2016). Monitoring global poverty a cover note to the report of the commission on global poverty, chaired by Prof. Sir Anthony B. Atkinson October 18, 2016. http://pubdocs.worldbank.org/en/733161476724983858/MonitoringGlobalPovertyCoverNote.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Yong, M. & Mulvale, J. P. (2009). Possibilities and prospects: The debate over a guaranteed income. An Economic Security Project ReportCanadian Centre for Policy Alternativeshttps://www.policyalternatives.ca/sites/default/files/uploads/publications/reports/docs/CCPA_Guaranteed_Income_Nov_2009.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Zelleke, A. (2011). Feminist political theory and the argument for an unconditional basic income. Policy & Politics, 39(1), 27–42.10.1332/030557311X546299Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2017-6-13

© 2017 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 24.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bis-2016-0005/html
Scroll to top button