Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The value of law

  • Published:
Theory and Society Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Much has been written about the value of law, mostly in ideational terms. In this article, I draw attention to law’s pecuniary value. Law, I argue, is the very stuff from which many wealth generating, or capital, assets are made, foremost among them intangible assets that account for most of the private wealth today. For law to serve as a fountain of wealth, it must be backed by state power, and indeed, sovereign states have been more than willing to offer a helping hand. They have found intellectual support in neoclassical economics and in its off-spring, law and economics, theoretical approaches that have sought to ground law in the scientific analysis of the economy, in efficiency rather than in justice. In doing so, they have averted their eyes from the fact that the most critical source for wealth, that is law, is itself of the state and should be subject to social norms enshrined in our constitutions, not abstract welfarism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aldasor, I., & Elers, T. (2018). The credit default swap market: What a different a decade makes. BIS Quarterly Review, 2018(June).

  • Alston, L. J. (1984). Farm foreclosure moratorium legislation: A lesson from the past. The American Economic Review, 74(3), 445–457.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alston, L. J. (2009). Farm foreclosures in the United States during the interwar period. Journal of Economic History, 43(04), 885–903. https://doi.org/10.1017/s0022050700030801.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baird, D. G. (1993). The elements of bankruptcy. New York: Westbury.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baisc Inc v. Levinson (1989). (Vol. 485, pp. 224): US Supreme Court.

  • Beck, U. (1992). Risk society: Towards a new modernity. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Board of Trade of City of Chcago v. Chrstie Grain & Stock Co. (1905). (Vol. 198, p. 236).

  • Bolton, P., & Rosenthal, H. (2002). Political intervention in debt contracts. Journal of Political Economy, 110(5), 1103–1134.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boodry, K. (2016). August Belmont and the world the slaves made. In S. Beckert & S. Rockman (Eds.), Slavery’s capitalism: A new history of American economic development (p. 163). Philadelphia: Pennsylvania University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Callon, M. (1998). Introduction: The Embeddedness of economic Markets in Economics. In M. Callon (Ed.), The Laws of the markets. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlson, M. A., & Wheelock, D. C. (2012). The Lender of Last Resort: Lessons from the Fed's First 100 Years. Paper presented at the current policy under the Lens of economic history: A conference to commemorate the Federal Reserve System's centennial, Cleveland, 13-14 December 2012.

  • Carruthers, B. (1996). City of capital: Politics and Markets in the English Financial Revolution. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carruthers, B. (2013). Diverging derivatives: Law, governance, and modern financial markets. Journal of Comparative Economics, 41(2), 386–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheun, S., Köppen-Mertes, V. & Weller, B. (2009). The Collateral Frameworks of the Eurosystem, the Federal Reserve System and the Bank of England and the Financial Market Turmoil. Occasional Paper Series, European Central Bank (107).

  • Chung, J. J. (2009). From feudal land contracts to financial derivatives: The treatment of status through specific relief (research paper 83). Roger Williams University School of Law, Legal Studies Research Paper Series.

  • Cohen, J. L. (2012). Globalization and sovereignty: Rethinking legality, legitimacy and constitutionalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Commons, J. R. (1924). The legal foundations of capitalism. New York: The MacMillan Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Commons, J. R. (1934). Institutional economics: Its place in political economy. New York: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • COP. (2010). The AIG rescue, its impact on markets, and the Government’s exit strategy. Washington DC: Congressional Oversight Panel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farago, J. M. (1980). Uncertainty and the Concdept of law. NYU Law Review, 55, 195–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilson, R., & Kraakman, R. (1984). The mechanisms of market efficiency. Virginia Law Review, 70(4), 549–644.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilson, R. J., & Kraakman, R. (2014). Market efficiency after the crisis: It's still a matter of information costs.

  • Gilson, R. J., Sabel, C. F., & Scott, R. E. (2009). Contracting for innovation: Vertical disintegration and Interfirm collaboration. Columbia Law Review, 109(3), 431–502.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilson, R., Sabel, C., & Scott, R. (2014). Text and context: Contracts and contract interpretation by design. Cornell Law Review, 100, 23–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G. (2017). The history and economics of safe assets. Annual Review of Economics, 9, 547–586.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G., & Metrick, A. (2012). Securitized banking and the run on repo. Journal of Financial Economics, 104(3), 425–451. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2011.03.016.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J., & Stiglitz, J. (1980). On the impossibility of efficient stock markets. American Economic Review, 70(3), 393–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O., & Moore, J. (1999). Foundations of incomplete contracts. Review of Economic Studies, 66(1).

  • Haskel, J., & Westlake, S. (2018). Capitalism without capital: The rise of the intangible economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Home Building & Loan Association v. Blaisdell (1934). (Vol. 290, pp. 398): US Supreme Court.

  • Jarrell, G. A. (1981). The economic effects of Federal Regulation of the market for new security issues. Journal of Law and Economics, XXIV(December), 613–675.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, L. (1992). Rules versus standards: An economic analysis. Duke Law Journal, 42, 557–629.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, L., & Shavell, S. (2001). Fairness versus Welfare. Harvard Law Review, 114(4), 961–1388.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, L., & Shavell, S. (2006). Fairness versus welfare. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreitner, R. (2000). Speculations of contract, or how contract law stopped worrying and learned to love risk. Columbia Law Review, 100(4), 1096. https://doi.org/10.2307/1123538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langbein, J. L. (1997). The secret life of the trust: The trust as an instrument of commerce. Yale Law Journal, 107(1), 165–189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitin, A. J., & Wachter, S. M. (2012). Explaining the housing bubble. The Georgetown Law Journal, 100(4), 1177–1258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Macaulay, S. (1962). Non-contractual relations in business: A preliminary study. American Sociological Review, 55–67.

  • Macey, J. R., & Miller, G. P. (1991). Origin of the blue sky Laws. Texas Law Review, 70, 347–397.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie, D. (2006). An engine, not a camera: How financial models shape markets. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Macneil, I. R. (1985). Relational contracts: What we do and do not know. Wisconsin Law Review, 1985(3), 483–525.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazzucato, M. (2018). The value of everything: Making and taking in the global economy. New York: Public Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehrling, P. (2011). The new Lombard street: How the fed became the dealer of last resort. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merrill, T. (1987). Public contracts, private contracts, and the transformation of the constitutional order. Case Western Reserve Law Review, 37(4), 597–630.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H. P. (1986). Stabilizing an unstable economy. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21st century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pistor, K. (2013). A legal theory of finance. Journal of Comparative Economics, 41(2), 315–330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pistor, K. (2019). The code of capital: How the law creates wealth and inequality. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pistor, K., & Xu, C. (2003). Incomplete law. Journal of International Law and Politics, 35(4), 931–1013.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi, K. (1944). The great transformation: The political and economic origins of our time. Boston: Beacon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. N. (1962). The panic of 1819. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saez, E., & Zucman, G. (2019). The triumph of injustice: How the rich dodge taxes and how to make them pay. New York: Norton Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salmon, F. (2011). Is Informationally-insensitive debt a good thing? Reuters. http://blogs.reuters.com/felix-salmon/2011/04/15/is-informationally-insensitive-debt-a-good-thing/.

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1965). Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly. Industrial Management Review, 6(2), 41–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, R. (2006). The law and economics of incomplete contracts. Annual Review of Law and Social Science, 2006(2), 279–297.

    Google Scholar 

  • Segoviano, M., Jones, B., Lindner, P., & Blankenheim, J. (2013). Securitization: Lessons learned and the road ahead. IMF Working Paper, 2013(255).

  • Skowronek, S. (1982). Building a new American state - the expansion of Naitonal administrative capacities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stout, L. A. (2011). Derivatives and the legal origin of the 2008 credit crisis. Harvard Business Law Review, 1(1), 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, C. (2006). Chevron Step Zero. Virginia Law Review, 92(9), 187–249.

    Google Scholar 

  • TSC Industries v. Northway (1976). (Vol. 426, pp. 438): US Supreme Court.

  • Veblen, T. (1908). On the nature of capital. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 22(4), 517–542.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. (1919). The place of science in modern civilization and other essays. New York: B.W. Huebsch.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1981). General economic history. Social Science Classics Series.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Katharina Pistor.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pistor, K. The value of law. Theor Soc 49, 165–186 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-020-09388-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-020-09388-z

Keywords

Navigation