Linked bibliography for the SEP article "Bounded Rationality" by Gregory Wheeler
This is an automatically generated and experimental page
If everything goes well, this page should display the bibliography of the aforementioned article as it appears in the Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, but with links added to PhilPapers records and Google Scholar for your convenience. Some bibliographies are not going to be represented correctly or fully up to date. In general, bibliographies of recent works are going to be much better linked than bibliographies of primary literature and older works. Entries with PhilPapers records have links on their titles. A green link indicates that the item is available online at least partially.
This experiment has been authorized by the editors of the Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. The original article and bibliography can be found here.
- Alexander, Jason McKenzie, 2007, The Structural Evolution of Morality, New York: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511550997 (Scholar)
- Alexander, Richard D., 1987, The Biology of Moral Systems, London: Routledge. (Scholar)
- Allais, Maurice, 1953, “Le Comportement de L’homme Rationnel Devant Le Risque: Critique Des Postulats et Axiomes de L’école Américaine”, Econometrica, 21(4): 503–546. doi:10.2307/1907921 (Scholar)
- Anand, Paul, 1987, “Are the Preference Axioms Really Rational?” Theory and Decision, 23(2): 189–214. doi:10.1007/bf00126305 (Scholar)
- Anderson, John R., 1991, “The Adaptive Nature of Human Categorization”, Psychological Review, 98(3): 409–429. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.98.3.409 (Scholar)
- Anderson, John R. and Lael J. Schooler, 1991, “Reflections of the Environment in Memory”, Psychological Science, 2(6): 396–408. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9280.1991.tb00174.x (Scholar)
- Arkes, Hal R., Gerd Gigerenzer, and Ralph Hertwig, 2016, “How Bad Is Incoherence?”, Decision, 3(1): 20–39. doi:10.1037/dec0000043 (Scholar)
- Arló-Costa, Horacio and Arthur Paul Pedersen, 2011, “Bounded Rationality: Models for Some Fast and Frugal Heuristics”, in A. Gupta, Johan van Benthem, & Eric Pacuit (eds.), Games, Norms and Reasons: Logic at the Crossroads, Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands. doi:10.1007/978-94-007-0714-6_1 (Scholar)
- Arrow, Kenneth, 2004, “Is Bounded Rationality Unboundedly Rational? Some Ruminations”, in M. Augier & J. G. March (eds.), Models of a Man: Essays in Memory of Herbert A. Simon, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 47–55. (Scholar)
- Aumann, Robert J., 1962, “Utility Theory without the Completeness Axiom”, Econometrica, 30(3): 445–462. doi:10.2307/1909888 (Scholar)
- –––, 1997, “Rationality and Bounded Rationality”, Games and Economic Behavior, 21(1–2): 2–17. doi:10.1006/game.1997.0585 (Scholar)
- Axelrod, Robert, 1984, The Evolution of Cooperation, New York: Basic Books. (Scholar)
- Ballard, Dana H. and Christopher M. Brown, 1982, Computer Vision, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. (Scholar)
- Bar-Hillel, Maya and Avishai Margalit, 1988, “How Vicious Are Cycles of Intransitive Choice?” Theory and Decision, 24(2): 119–145. doi:10.1007/bf00132458 (Scholar)
- Bar-Hillel, Maya and Willem A Wagenaar, 1991, “The Perception of Randomness”, Advances in Applied Mathematics, 12(4): 428–454. doi:10.1016/0196-8858(91)90029-i (Scholar)
- Barabási, Albert-László and Reka Albert, 1999, “Emergence of Scaling in Random Networks”, Science, 286(5439): 509–512. doi:10.1126/science.286.5439.509 (Scholar)
- Barkow, Jerome, Leda Cosmides, and John Tooby (eds.), 1992, The Adapted Mind: Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture, New York: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Baumeister, Roy F., Ellen Bratslavsky, Catrin Finkenauer, and Kathleen D. Vohs, 2001, “Bad Is Stronger than Good.”, Review of General Psychology, 5(4): 323–370. doi:10.1037/1089-2680.5.4.323 (Scholar)
- Bazerman, Max H. and Don A. Moore, 2008, Judgment in Managerial Decision Making seventh edition, New York: Wiley. (Scholar)
- Bell, David E., 1982, “Regret in Decision Making Under Uncertainty”, Operations Research, 30(5): 961–981. doi:10.1287/opre.30.5.961 (Scholar)
- Bennett, Jonathan, 1964, Rationality: An Essay Towards an Analysis, London: Routledge. (Scholar)
- Berger, James O., 1980, Statistical Decision Theory and Bayesian Analysis, second edition, New York: Springer. doi:10.1007/978-1-4757-4286-2 (Scholar)
- Bernoulli, Daniel, 1738, “Exposition of a New Theory on the Measurement of Risk”, Econometrica, 22(1): 23–36. doi:10.2307/1909829 (Scholar)
- Bewley, Truman S., 2002, “Knightian Decision Theory: Part I”, Decisions in Economics and Finance, 25(2): 79–110. doi:10.1007/s102030200006 (Scholar)
- Bicchieri, Cristina, 2005, The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511616037 (Scholar)
- Bicchieri, Cristina and Ryan Muldoon, 2014, “Social Norms”, in The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, (Spring 2014), Edward N. Zalta (ed.), URL = <https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2014/entries/social-norms/> (Scholar)
- Birnbaum, Michael H., 1983, “Base Rates in Bayesian Inference: Signal Detection Analysis of the Cab Problem”, The American Journal of Psychology, 96(1): 85–94. doi:10.2307/1422211 (Scholar)
- Bishop, Christopher M., 2006, Pattern Recognition and Machine Learning, New York: Springer. (Scholar)
- Blume, Lawrence, Adam Brandenburger, and Eddie Dekel, 1991, “Lexicographic Probabilities and Choice Under Uncertainty”, Econometrica, 58(1): 61–78. doi:10.2307/2938240 (Scholar)
- Bonet, Blai and Héctor Geffner, 2001, “Planning as Heuristic Search”, Artificial Intelligence, 129(1–2): 5–33. doi:10.1016/s0004-3702(01)00108-4 (Scholar)
- Bowles, Samuel and Herbert Gintis, 2011, A Cooperative Species: Human Reciprocity and Its Evolution, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. doi:10.23943/princeton/9780691151250.001.0001 (Scholar)
- Boyd, Robert and Peter J. Richerson, 2005, The Origin and Evolution of Cultures, New York: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Brown, Scott D. and Andrew Heathcote, 2008, “The Simplest Complete Model of Choice Response Time: Linear Ballistic Accumulation”, Cognitive Psychology, 57(3): 153–178. doi:10.1016/j.cogpsych.2007.12.002 (Scholar)
- Brunswik, Egon, 1943, “Organismic Achievement and Environmental Probability”, Psychological Review, 50(3): 255–272. doi:10.1037/h0060889 (Scholar)
- –––, 1955, “Representative Design and Probabilistic Theory in a Functional Psychology”, Psychological Review, 62(3): 193–217. doi:10.1037/h0047470 (Scholar)
- Charness, Gary and Peter J. Kuhn, 2011, “Lab Labor: What Can Labor Economists Learn from the Lab?” in Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 4, pp. 229–330, Elsevier. doi:10.1016/s0169-7218(11)00409-6 (Scholar)
- Chater, Nick, 2014, “Cognitive Science as an Interface Between Rational and Mechanistic Explanation”, Topics in Cognitive Science, 6(2): 331–337. doi:10.1111/tops.12087 (Scholar)
- Chater, Nick, Mike Oaksford, Ramin Nakisa, and Martin Redington, 2003, “Fast, Frugal, and Rational: How Rational Norms Explain Behavior”, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 90(1): 63–86. doi:10.1016/s0749-5978(02)00508-3 (Scholar)
- Clark, Andy and David Chalmers, 1998, “The Extended Mind”, Analysis, 58(1): 7–19. doi:10.1093/analys/58.1.7 (Scholar)
- Cohen, L. Jonathan, 1981, “Can Human Irrationality Be Experimentally Demonstrated?” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 4(3): 317–331. doi:10.1017/s0140525x00009092 (Scholar)
- Coletii, Giulianella and Romano Scozzafava, 2002, Probabilistic Logic in a Coherent Setting, (Trends in Logic, 15), Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands. doi:10.1007/978-94-010-0474-9 (Scholar)
- Czerlinski, Jean, Gerd Gigerenzer, and Daniel G. Goldstein, 1999, “How Good Are Simple Heuristics?” in Gigerenzer et al. 1999: 97–118. (Scholar)
- Damore, James A. and Jeff Gore, 2012, “Understanding Microbial Cooperation”, Journal of Theoretical Biology, 299: 31–41. doi:10.1016/j.jtbi.2011.03.008 (Scholar)
- Dana, Jason and Robin M. Dawes, 2004, “The Superiority of Simple Alternatives to Regression for Social Science Predictions”, Journal of Educational and Behavioral Statistics, 29(3): 317–331. doi:10.3102/10769986029003317 (Scholar)
- Darwin, Charles, 1871, The Descent of Man, New York: D. Appleton and Company. (Scholar)
- Davidson, Donald, 1974, “Belief and the Basis of Meaning”, Synthese, 27(3–4): 309–323. doi:10.1007/bf00484597 (Scholar)
- Davis-Stober, Clintin P., Jason Dana, and David V. Budescu, 2010, “Why Recognition Is Rational: Optimality Results on Single-Variable Decision Rules”, Judgment and Decision Making, 5(4): 216–229. (Scholar)
- Dawes, Robin M., 1979, “The Robust Beauty of Improper Linear Models in Decision Making”, American Psychologist, 34(7): 571–582. doi:10.1037/0003-066x.34.7.571 (Scholar)
- de Finetti, Bruno, 1970 [1974], Teoria Delle Probabilita, Italy: Giulio Einaudi. Translated as Theory of Probability: A Critical Introductory Treatment. Vol. 1 and 2, Antonio Machí and Adrian Smith (trans.), Chichester: Wiley, 1974. doi:10.1002/9781119286387 (Scholar)
- de Finetti, Bruno and Leonard J. Savage, 1962, “Sul Modo Di Scegliere Le Probabilità Iniziali”, Biblioteca Del Metron, Serie C, 1: 81–154. (Scholar)
- DeMiguel, Victor, Lorenzo Garlappi, and Raman Uppal, 2009, “Optimal Versus Naive Diversification: How Inefficient Is the \(\frac{1}{N}\) Portfolio Strategy?”, Review of Financial Studies, 22(5): 1915–1953. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhm075 (Scholar)
- Dennett, Daniel C., 1971, “Intentional Systems”, Journal of Philosophy, 68(4): 87–106. doi:10.2307/2025382 (Scholar)
- Dewey, John, 1960, The Quest for Certainty, New York: Capricorn Books. (Scholar)
- Dhami, Mandeep K., Ralph Hertwig, and Ulrich Hoffrage, 2004, “The Role of Representative Design in an Ecological Approach to Cognition”, Psychological Bulletin, 130(6): 959–988. doi:10.1037/0033-2909.130.6.959 (Scholar)
- Domingos, Pedro, 2000, “A Unified Bias-Variance Decomposition and Its Applications”, in Proceedings of the 17th International Conference on Machine Learning, Morgan Kaufmann, pp. 231–238. (Scholar)
- Doyen, Stéphane, Olivier Klein, Cora-Lise Pichton, and Axel Cleeremans, 2012, “Behavioral Priming: It’s All in the Mind, but Whose Mind?” PLoS One, 7(1): e29081. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0029081 (Scholar)
- Dubins, Lester E., 1975, “Finitely Additive Conditional Probability, Conglomerability, and Disintegrations”, Annals of Probability, 3(1): 89–99. doi:10.1214/aop/1176996451 (Scholar)
- Einhorn, Hillel J., 1970, “The Use of Nonlinear, Noncompensatory Models in Decision Making”, Psychological Bulletin, 73(3): 221–230. doi:10.1037/h0028695 (Scholar)
- Elliott, Graham, Ivana Komunjer, and Allan Timmermann, 2005, “Estimation and Testing of Forecast Rationality under Flexible Loss”, Review of Economic Studies, 72(4): 1107–1125. doi:10.1111/0034-6527.00363 (Scholar)
- Ellsberg, Daniel, 1961, “Risk, Ambiguity and the Savage Axioms”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75(4): 643–669. doi:10.2307/1884324 (Scholar)
- Fawcett, Tim W., Benja Fallenstein, Andrew D. Higginson, Alasdair I. Houston, Dave E.W. Mallpress, Pete C. Trimmer, and John M. McNamara, 2014, “The Evolution of Decision Rules in Complex Environments”, Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 18(3): 153–161. doi:10.1016/j.tics.2013.12.012 (Scholar)
- Fennema, Hein and Peter Wakker, 1997, “Original and Cumulative Prospect Theory: A Discussion of Empirical Differences”, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 10(1): 53–64. doi:10.1002/(sici)1099-0771(199703)10:1<53::AID-BDM245>3.0.CO;2-1 (Scholar)
- Fiedler, Klaus, 1988, “The Dependence of the Conjunction Fallacy on Subtle Linguistic Factors”, Psychological Research, 50(2): 123–129. doi:10.1007/bf00309212 (Scholar)
- Fiedler, Klaus and Peter Juslin (eds.), 2006, Information Sampling and Adaptive Cognition, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511614576 (Scholar)
- Fishburn, Peter C., 1982, The Foundations of Expected Utility, Dordrecht: D. Reidel. doi:10.1007/978-94-017-3329-8 (Scholar)
- Fisher, Ronald Aylmer, 1936, “Uncertain Inference”, Proceedings of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences, 71(4): 245–258. doi:10.2307/20023225 (Scholar)
- Friedman, Jerome, 1997, “On Bias, Variance, 0-1 Loss and the Curse of Dimensionality”, Journal of Data Mining and Knowledge Discovery, 1(1): 55–77. doi:10.1023/a:1009778005914 (Scholar)
- Friedman, Milton, 1953, “The Methodology of Positive Economics”, in Essays in Positive Economics, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 3–43. (Scholar)
- Friedman, Milton and Leonard J. Savage, 1948, “The Utility Analysis of Choices Involving Risk”, Journal of Political Economy, 56(4): 279–304. doi:10.1086/256692 (Scholar)
- Friston, Karl, 2010, “The Free-Energy Principle: A Unified Brain Theory?”, Nature Reviews Neuroscience, 11(2): 127–138. doi:10.1038/nrn2787 (Scholar)
- Galaabaatar, Tsogbadral and Edi Karni, 2013, “Subjective Expected Utility with Incomplete Preferences”, Econometrica, 81(1): 255–284. doi:10.3982/ecta9621 (Scholar)
- Gergely, György, Harold Bekkering, and Ildikó Király, 2002, “Developmental Psychology: Rational Imitation in Preverbal Infants”, Nature, 415(6873): 755–755. doi:10.1038/415755a (Scholar)
- Ghallab, Malik, Dana Nau, and Paolo Traverso, 2016, Automated Planning and Acting, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9781139583923 (Scholar)
- Gibson, James J., 1979, The Ecological Approach to Visual Perception, Boston: Houghton Mifflin. (Scholar)
- Gigerenzer, Gerd, 1996, “On Narrow Norms and Vague Heuristics: A Reply to Kahneman and Tversky”, Psychological Review, 103(3): 592–596. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.103.3.592 (Scholar)
- –––, 2007, Gut Feelings: The Intelligence of the Unconscious, New York: Viking Press. (Scholar)
- Gigerenzer, Gerd and Henry Brighton, 2009, “Homo Heuristicus: Why Biased Minds Make Better Inferences”, Topics in Cognitive Science, 1(1): 107–143. doi:10.1111/j.1756-8765.2008.01006.x (Scholar)
- Gigerenzer, Gerd and Daniel G. Goldstein, 1996, “Reasoning the Fast and Frugal Way: Models of Bounded Rationality”, Psychological Review, 103(4): 650–669. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.103.4.650 (Scholar)
- Gigerenzer, Gerd, Wolfgang Hell, and Hartmut Blank, 1988, “Presentation and Content: The Use of Base Rates as a Continuous Variable.”, Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 14(3): 513–525. doi:10.1037/0096-1523.14.3.513 (Scholar)
- Gigerenzer, Gerd, Ralph Hertwig, and Thorsten Pachur (eds), 2011, Heuristics: The Foundations of Adaptive Behavior, Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199744282.001.0001 (Scholar)
- Gigerenzer, Gerd, Peter M. Todd, and the ABC Group (eds.), 1999, Simple Heuristics That Make Us Smart, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Giles, Robin, 1976, “A Logic for Subjective Belief”, in Foundations of Probability Theory, Statistical Inference, and Statistical Theories of Science, William L. Harper and Clifford Alan Hooker (eds.), Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands, vol. I: 41–72. doi:10.1007/978-94-010-1853-1_4 (Scholar)
- Giron, F. J., and S. Rios, 1980, “Quasi-Bayesian Behavior: A More Realistic Approach to Decision Making?” Trabajos de Estadistica Y de Investigacion Operativa, 31(1): 17–38. doi:10.1007/bf02888345 (Scholar)
- Glymour, Clark, 2001, The Mind’s Arrows, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. (Scholar)
- Goldblatt, Robert, 1998, Lectures on the Hyperreals: An Introduction to Nonstandard Analysis, (Graduate Texts in Mathematics 188), New York: Springer New York. doi:10.1007/978-1-4612-0615-6 (Scholar)
- Goldstein, Daniel G. and Gerd Gigerenzer, 2002, “Models of Ecological Rationality: The Recognition Heuristic.”, Psychological Review, 109(1): 75–90. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.109.1.75 (Scholar)
- Golub, Benjamin and Matthew O Jackson, 2010, “Naïve Learning in Social Networks and the Wisdom of Crowds”, American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2(1): 112–149. doi:10.1257/mic.2.1.112 (Scholar)
- Good, Irving J., 1952, “Rational Decisions”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series B, 14(1): 107–114. Reprinted in Good 1983: 3–14 (Scholar)
- –––, 1967, “On the Principle of Total Evidence”, The British Journal for the Philosophy of Science, 17(4): 319–321. Reprinted in Good 1983: 178–180. doi:10.1093/bjps/17.4.319 (Scholar)
- –––, 1971 [1983], “Twenty-Seven Principles of Rationality”, Foundations of Statistical Inference, V. P. Godambe and D. A. Sprott (eds), Toronto: Holt, Rinehart & Winston. Reprinted in Good 1983: 15–20. (Scholar)
- –––, 1983, Good Thinking: The Foundations of Probability and Its Applications, Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. (Scholar)
- Güth, Werner, Rolf Schmittberger, and Bernd Schwarze, 1982, “An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3(4): 367–388. doi:10.1016/0167-2681(82)90011-7 (Scholar)
- Hacking, Ian, 1967, “Slightly More Realistic Personal Probability”, Philosophy of Science, 34(4): 311–325. doi:10.1086/288169 (Scholar)
- Haenni, Rolf, Jan-Willem Romeijn, Gregory Wheeler, and Jon Williamson, 2011, Probabilistic Logics and Probabilistic Networks, Dordrecht: Springer Netherlands. doi:10.1007/978-94-007-0008-6 (Scholar)
- Hahn, Ulrike and Paul A. Warren, 2009, “Perceptions of Randomness: Why Three Heads Are Better Than Four”, Psychological Review, 116(2): 454–461. doi:10.1037/a0015241 (Scholar)
- Halpern, Joseph Y., 2010, “Lexicographic Probability, Conditional Probability, and Nonstandard Probability”, Games and Economic Behavior, 68(1): 155–179. doi:10.1016/j.geb.2009.03.013 (Scholar)
- Hammond, Kenneth R., 1955, “Probabilistic Functioning and the Clinical Method”, Psychological Review, 62(4): 255–262. doi:10.1037/h0046845 (Scholar)
- Hammond, Kenneth R., Carolyn J. Hursch, and Frederick J. Todd, 1964, “Analyzing the Components of Clinical Inference”, Psychological Review, 71(6): 438–456. doi:10.1037/h0040736 (Scholar)
- Hammond, Peter J., 1994, “Elementary Non-Archimedean Representations of Probability for Decision Theory and Games”, in Paul Humphreys (ed.), Patrick Suppes: Scientific Philosopher, Vol. 1: Probability and Probabilistic Causality, Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer, pp. 25–59. doi:10.1007/978-94-011-0774-7_2 (Scholar)
- Haykin, Simon O., 2013, Adaptive Filter Theory, fifth edition, London: Pearson. (Scholar)
- Henrich, Joseph and Francisco J Gil-White, 2001, “The Evolution of Prestige: Freely Conferred Deference as a Mechanism for Enhancing the Benefits of Cultural Transmission”, Evolution and Human Behavior, 22(3): 165–196. doi:10.1016/s1090-5138(00)00071-4 (Scholar)
- Hertwig, Ralph and Gerd Gigerenzer, 1999, “The ‘Conjunction Fallacy’ Revisited: How Intelligent Inferences Look Like Reasoning Errors”, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 12(4): 275–305. doi:10.1002/(sici)1099-0771(199912)12:4<275::AID-BDM323>3.0.CO;2-M (Scholar)
- Hertwig, Ralph and Timothy J. Pleskac, 2008, “The Game of Life: How Small Samples Render Choice Simpler”, in The Probabilistic Mind: Prospects for Bayesian Cognitive Science, Nick Chater and Mike Oaksford (eds.), Oxford: Oxford University Press, 209–236. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780199216093.003.0010 (Scholar)
- Hertwig, Ralph, Greg Barron, Elke U. Weber, and Ido Erev, 2004, “Decisions from Experience and the Effect of Rare Events in Risky Choice”, Psychological Science, 15(8): 534–539. doi:10.1111/j.0956-7976.2004.00715.x (Scholar)
- Hertwig, Ralph, Jennifer Nerissa Davis, and Frank J. Sulloway, 2002, “Parental Investment: How an Equity Motive Can Produce Inequality”, Psychological Bulletin, 128(5): 728–745. doi:10.1037/0033-2909.128.5.728 (Scholar)
- Herzog, Stefan M. and Ralph Hertwig, 2013, “The Ecological Validity of Fluency”, in Christian Unkelbach & Rainer Greifeneder (eds.), The Experience of Thinking: How Fluency of Mental Processes Influences Cognition and Behavior,, Psychology Press, pp. 190–219. (Scholar)
- Hey, John D., 1982, “Search for Rules for Search”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3(1): 65–81. doi:10.1016/0167-2681(82)90004-x (Scholar)
- Ho, Teck-Hua, 1996, “Finite Automata Play Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma with Information Processing Costs”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 20(1–3): 173–207. doi:10.1016/0165-1889(94)00848-1 (Scholar)
- Hochman, Guy and Eldad Yechiam, 2011, “Loss Aversion in the Eye and in the Heart: The Autonomic Nervous System’s Responses to Losses”, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 24(2): 140–156. doi:10.1002/bdm.692 (Scholar)
- Hogarth, Robin M., 2012, “When Simple Is Hard to Accept”, in Todd et al. 2012: 61–79. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195315448.003.0024 (Scholar)
- Hogarth, Robin M. and Natalia Karelaia, 2007, “Heuristic and Linear Models of Judgment: Matching Rules and Environments”, Psychological Review, 114(3): 733–758. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.114.3.733 (Scholar)
- Howe, Mark L., 2011, “The Adaptive Nature of Memory and Its Illusions”, Current Directions in Psychological Science, 20(5): 312–315. doi:10.1177/0963721411416571 (Scholar)
- Hume, David, 1738 [2008], A Treatise of Human Nature, Jonathan Bennett (ed.), www.earlymoderntexts.com, 2008. [Hume 1738 available online] (Scholar)
- Hutchinson, John M., Carola Fanselow, and Peter M. Todd, 2012, “Car Parking as a Game Between Simple Heuristics”, in Todd et al. 2012: 454–484. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195315448.003.0133 (Scholar)
- Jackson, Matthew O., 2010, Social and Economic Networks, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. (Scholar)
- Jarvstad, Andreas, Ulrike Hahn, Simon K. Rushton, and Paul A. Warren, 2013, “Perceptuo-Motor, Cognitive, and Description-Based Decision-Making Seem Equally Good”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 110(40): 16271–16276. doi:10.1073/pnas.1300239110 (Scholar)
- Jevons, William Stanley, 1871, The Theory of Political Economy, London: Macmillian; Company. (Scholar)
- Juslin, Peter and Henrik Olsson, 2005, “Capacity Limitations and the Detection of Correlations: Comment on Kareev”, Psychological Review, 112(1): 256–267. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.112.1.256 (Scholar)
- Juslin, Peter, Anders Winman, and Patrik Hansson, 2007, “The Naïve Intuitive Statistician: A Naïve Sampling Model of Intuitive Confidence Intervals.”, Psychological Review, 114(3): 678–703. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.114.3.678 (Scholar)
- Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky, 1972, “Subjective Probability: A Judgment of Representativeness”, Cognitive Psychology, 3(3): 430–454. doi:10.1016/0010-0285(72)90016-3 (Scholar)
- –––, 1979, “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk”, Econometrica, 47(2): 263–291. doi:10.2307/1914185 (Scholar)
- –––, 1996, “On the Reality of Cognitive Illusions”, Psychological Review, 103(3): 582–591. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.103.3.582 (Scholar)
- Kahneman, Daniel, Baruch Slovic, and Amos Tversky (eds.), 1982, Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511809477 (Scholar)
- Kareev, Yaakov, 1995, “Through a Narrow Window: Working Memory Capacity and the Detection of Covariation”, Cognition, 56(3): 263–269. doi:10.1016/0010-0277(95)92814-g (Scholar)
- –––, 2000, “Seven (Indeed, Plus or Minus Two) and the Detection of Correlations”, Psychological Review, 107(2): 397–402. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.107.2.397 (Scholar)
- Karni, Edi, 1985, Decision Making Under Uncertainty: The Case of State-Dependent Preferences, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University. (Scholar)
- Katsikopoulos, Konstantinos V., 2010, “The Less-Is-More Effect: Predictions and Tests”, Judgment and Decision Making, 5(4): 244–257. (Scholar)
- Katsikopoulos, Konstantinos V., Lael J. Schooler, and Ralph Hertwig, 2010, “The Robust Beauty of Ordinary Information”, Psychological Review, 117(4): 1259–1266. doi:10.1037/a0020418 (Scholar)
- Kaufmann, Esther and Werner W. Wittmann, 2016, “The Success of Linear Bootstrapping Models: Decision Domain-, Expertise-, and Criterion-Specific Meta-Analysis”, PLoS One, 11(6): e0157914. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0157914 (Scholar)
- Keeney, Ralph L. and Howard Raiffa, 1976, Decisions with Multiple Objectives: Preferences and Value Trade-Offs, New York: Wiley. (Scholar)
- Kelly, Kevin T. and Oliver Schulte, 1995, “The Computable Testability of Theories Making Uncomputable Predictions”, Erkenntnis, 43(1): 29–66. doi:10.1007/bf01131839 (Scholar)
- Keynes, John Maynard, 1921, A Treatise on Probability, London: Macmillan. (Scholar)
- Kidd, Celeste and Benjamin Y. Hayden, 2015, “The Psychology and Neuroscience of Curiosity”, Neuron, 88(3): 449–460. doi:10.1016/j.neuron.2015.09.010 (Scholar)
- Kirsh, David, 1995, “The Intelligent Use of Space”, Artificial Intelligence, 73(1–2): 31–68. doi:10.1016/0004-3702(94)00017-u (Scholar)
- Klaes, Matthias and Esther-Mirjam Sent, 2005, “A Conceptual History of the Emergence of Bounded Rationality”, History of Political Economy, 37(1):27–59. doi:10.1215/00182702-37-1-27 (Scholar)
- Knight, Frank H., 1921, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, Boston: Houghton Mifflin. (Scholar)
- Koehler, Jonathan J., 1996, “The Base Rate Fallacy Reconsidered: Descriptive, Normative, and Methodological Challenges”, Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 19(1): 1–53. doi:10.1017/s0140525x00041157 (Scholar)
- Koopman, Bernard O., 1940, “The Axioms and Algebra of Intuitive Probability”, Annals of Mathematics, 41(2): 269–292. doi:10.2307/1969003 (Scholar)
- Körding, Konrad Paul and Daniel M. Wolpert, 2004, “The Loss Function of Sensorimotor Learning”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 101(26): 9839–9842. doi:10.1073/pnas.0308394101 (Scholar)
- Kreps, David M, Paul Milgrom, John Roberts, and Robert Wilson, 1982, “Rational Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoners’ Dilemma”, Journal of Economic Theory, 27(2): 245–252. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(82)90029-1 (Scholar)
- Kühberger, Anton, Michael Schulte-Mecklenbeck, and Josef Perner, 1999, “The Effects of Framing, Reflection, Probability, and Payoff on Risk Preference in Choice Tasks”, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 78(3): 204–231. doi:10.1006/obhd.1999.2830 (Scholar)
- Kyburg, Henry E., Jr., 1978, “Subjective Probability: Criticisms, Reflections, and Problems”, Journal of Philosophical Logic, 7(1): 157–180. doi:10.1007/bf00245926 (Scholar)
- Levi, Isaac, 1977, “Direct Inference”, Journal of Philosophy, 74: 5–29. doi:10.2307/2025732 (Scholar)
- –––, 1983, “Who Commits the Base Rate Fallacy?”, Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 6(3): 502–506. doi:10.1017/s0140525x00017209 (Scholar)
- Lewis, Richard L., Andrew Howes, and Satinder Singh, 2014, “Computational Rationality: Linking Mechanism and Behavior Through Bounded Utility Maximization”, Topics in Cognitive Science, 6(2): 279–311. doi:10.1111/tops.12086 (Scholar)
- Lichtenberg, Jan Malte and Özgür Simsek, 2016, “Simple Regression Models”, Proceedings of Machine Learning Research, 58: 13–25. (Scholar)
- Loomes, Graham and Robert Sugden, 1982, “Regret Theory: An Alternative Theory of Rational Choice Under Uncertainty”, Economic Journal, 92(368): 805–824. doi:10.2307/2232669 (Scholar)
- Loridan, P., 1984, “\(\epsilon\)-Solutions in Vector Minimization Problems”, Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 43(2): 265–276. doi:10.1007/bf00936165 (Scholar)
- Luce, R. Duncan and Howard Raiffa, 1957, Games and Decisions: Introduction and Critical Suvey, New York: Dover. (Scholar)
- Marr, D. C., 1982, Vision, New York: Freeman. (Scholar)
- May, Kenneth O., 1954, “Intransitivity, Utility, and the Aggregation of Preference Patterns”, Econometrica, 22(1): 1–13. doi:10.2307/1909827 (Scholar)
- Maynard Smith, John, 1982, Evolution and the Theory of Games, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511806292 (Scholar)
- McBeath, Michael K., Dennis M. Shaffer, and Mary K. Kaiser, 1995, “How Baseball Outfielders Determine Where to Run to Catch Fly Balls”, Science, 268(5210): 569–573. doi:10.1126/science.7725104 (Scholar)
- McNamara, John M., Pete C. Trimmer, and Alasdair I. Houston, 2014, “Natural Selection Can Favour `Irrational’ Behavior”, Biology Letters, 10(1): 20130935. doi:10.1098/rsbl.2013.0935 (Scholar)
- Meder, Björn, Ralf Mayrhofer, and Michael R. Waldmann, 2014, “Structure Induction in Diagnostic Causal Reasoning”, Psychological Review, 121(3): 277–301. doi:10.1037/a0035944 (Scholar)
- Meehl, Paul, 1954, Clinical Versus Statistical Prediction: A Theoretical Analysis and a Review of the Evidence, Minneapolis: Minnesota Press. (Scholar)
- Mill, John Stuart, 1844, “On the Definition of Political Economy”, reprinted in John M. Robson (ed.), The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Vol. IV, Toronto: University of Toronto Press. (Scholar)
- Mongin, Philippe, 2000, “Does Optimization Imply Rationality”, Synthese, 124(1–2): 73–111. doi:10.1023/a:1005150001309 (Scholar)
- Nau, Robert, 2006, “The Shape of Incomplete Preferences”, The Annals of Statistics, 34(5): 2430–2448. doi:10.1214/009053606000000740 (Scholar)
- Neumann, John von and Oskar Morgenstern, 1944, Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. (Scholar)
- Newell, Allen and Herbert A. Simon, 1956, The Logic Theory Machine: A Complex Information Processing System (No. P-868), Santa Monica, CA: The Rand Corporation. (Scholar)
- –––, 1972, Human Problem Solving, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. (Scholar)
- –––, 1976, “Computer Science as Empirical Inquiry: Symbols and Search”, Communications of the ACM, 19(3): 113–126. doi:10.1145/360018.360022 (Scholar)
- Neyman, Abraham, 1985, “Bounded Complexity Justifies Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoners’ Dilemma”, Economics Letters, 19(3): 227–229. doi:10.1016/0165-1765(85)90026-6 (Scholar)
- Norton, Michael I., Daniel Mochon, and Dan Ariely, 2012, “The IKEA Effect: When Labor Leads to Love”, Journal of Consumer Psychology, 22(3): 453–460. doi:10.1016/j.jcps.2011.08.002 (Scholar)
- Nowak, Martin A. and Robert M. May, 1992, “Evolutionary Games and Spatial Chaos”, Nature, 359(6398): 826–829. doi:10.1038/359826a0 (Scholar)
- Oaksford, Mike and Nick Chater, 1994, “A Rational Analysis of the Selection Task as Optimal Data Selection”, Psychological Review, 101(4): 608–631. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.101.4.608 (Scholar)
- –––, 2007, Bayesian Rationality, Oxford: Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198524496.001.0001 (Scholar)
- Ok, Efe A., 2002, “Utility Representation of an Incomplete Preference Relation”, Journal of Economic Theory, 104(2): 429–449. doi:10.1006/jeth.2001.2814 (Scholar)
- Osborne, Martin J., 2003, An Introduction to Game Theory, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Oswald, Frederick L., Gregory Mitchell, Hart Blanton, James Jaccard, and Philip E. Tetlock, 2013, “Predicting Ethnic and Racial Discrimination: A Meta-Analysis of IAT Criterion Studies.”, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 105(2): 171–192. doi:10.1037/a0032734 (Scholar)
- Pachur, Thorsten, Peter M. Todd, Gerd Gigerenzer, Lael J. Schooler, and Daniel Goldstein, 2012, “When Is the Recognition Heuristic an Adaptive Tool?” in Todd et al. 2012: 113–143. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195315448.003.0035 (Scholar)
- Palmer, Stephen E., 1999, Vision Science, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. (Scholar)
- Papadimitriou, Christos H. and Mihalis Yannakakis, 1994, “On Complexity as Bounded Rationality (Extended Abstract)”, in Proceedings of the Twenty-Sixth Annual ACM Symposium on Theory of Computing - STOC ’94, Montreal: ACM Press, 726–733. doi:10.1145/195058.195445 (Scholar)
- Parikh, Rohit, 1971, “Existence and Feasibility in Arithmetic”, Journal of Symbolic Logic, 36(3): 494–508. doi:10.2307/2269958 (Scholar)
- Payne, John W., James R. Bettman, and Eric J. Johnson, 1988, “Adaptive Strategy Selection in Decision Making.”, Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 14(3): 534–552. doi:10.1037/0278-7393.14.3.534 (Scholar)
- Pedersen, Arthur Paul, 2014, “Comparative Expectations”, Studia Logica, 102(4): 811–848. doi:10.1007/s11225-013-9539-7 (Scholar)
- Pedersen, Arthur Paul and Gregory Wheeler, 2014, “Demystifying Dilation”, Erkenntnis, 79(6): 1305–1342. doi:10.1007/s10670-013-9531-7 (Scholar)
- –––, 2015, “Dilation, Disintegrations, and Delayed Decisions”, in Proceedings of the 9th Symposium on Imprecise Probabilities and Their Applications (Isipta), Pescara, Italy, pp. 227–236. (Scholar)
- Peirce, Charles S., 1955, Philosophical Writings of Peirce, Justus Buchler (ed.), New York: Dover. (Scholar)
- Peterson, Cameron R. and Lee Roy Beach, 1967, “Man as an Intuitive Statistician”, Psychological Bulletin, 68(1): 29–46. doi:10.1037/h0024722 (Scholar)
- Popper, Karl R., 1959, The Logic of Scientific Discovery, London: Routledge. (Scholar)
- Puranam, Phanish, Nils Stieglitz, Magda Osman, and Madan M. Pillutla, 2015, “Modelling Bounded Rationality in Organizations: Progress and Prospects”, The Academy of Management Annals, 9(1): 337–392. doi:10.1080/19416520.2015.1024498 (Scholar)
- Quiggin, John, 1982, “A Theory of Anticipated Utility”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3(4): 323–343. doi:10.1016/0167-2681(82)90008-7 (Scholar)
- Rabin, Matthew, 2000, “Risk Aversion and Expected-Utility Theory: A Calibration Theorem”, Econometrica, 68(5): 1281–1292. doi:10.1111/1468-0262.00158 (Scholar)
- Rapoport, Amnon, Darryl A. Seale, and Andrew M. Colman, 2015, “Is Tit-for-Tat the Answer? On the Conclusions Drawn from Axelrod’s Tournaments”, PLoS One, 10(7): e0134128. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0134128 (Scholar)
- Rapoport, Anatol and A.M. Chammah, 1965, Prisoner’s Dilemma: A Study in Conflict and Cooperation, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. (Scholar)
- Regenwetter, Michel, Jason Dana, and Clintin P. Davis-Stober, 2011, “Transitivity of Preferences”, Psychological Review, 118(1): 42–56. doi:10.1037/a0021150 (Scholar)
- Reiter, Ray, 1980, “A Logic for Default Reasoning”, Artificial Intelligence, 13(1–2): 81–132. doi:10.1016/0004-3702(80)90014-4 (Scholar)
- Rényi, Alfréd, 1955, “On a New Axiomatic Theory of Probability”, Acta Mathematica Academiae Scientiarum Hungaricae, 6(3–4): 285–335. doi:10.1007/bf02024393 (Scholar)
- Rick, Scott, 2011, “Losses, Gains, and Brains: Neuroeconomics Can Help to Answer Open Questions About Loss Aversion”, Journal of Consumer Psychology, 21(4): 453–463. doi:10.1016/j.jcps.2010.04.004 (Scholar)
- Rieskamp, Jörg and Anja Dieckmann, 2012, “Redundancy: Environment Structure That Simple Heuristics Can Exploit”, in Todd et al. 2012: 187–215. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195315448.003.0056 (Scholar)
- Rubinstein, Ariel, 1986, “Finite Automata Play the Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma”, Journal of Economic Theory, 39(1): 83–96. doi:10.1016/0022-0531(86)90021-9 (Scholar)
- Russell, Stuart J., and Subramanian, Devika, 1995, “Provably Bounded-Optimal Agents”, Journal of Artificial Intelligence Research, 2(1): 575–609. doi:10.1613/jair.133 (Scholar)
- Samuels, Richard, Stephen Stich, and Michael Bishop, 2002, “Ending the Rationality Wars: How to Make Disputes About Human Rationality Disappear”, in Common Sense, Reasoning, and Rationality, Renee Elio (ed.), New York: Oxford University Press, 236–268. doi:10.1093/0195147669.003.0011 (Scholar)
- Samuelson, Paul, 1947, Foundations of Economic Analysis, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. (Scholar)
- Santos, Francisco C., Marta D. Santos, and Jorge M. Pacheco, 2008, “Social Diversity Promotes the Emergence of Cooperation in Public Goods Games”, Nature, 454(7201): 213–216. doi:10.1038/nature06940 (Scholar)
- Savage, Leonard J., 1954, Foundations of Statistics, New York: Wiley. (Scholar)
- –––, 1967, “Difficulties in the Theory of Personal Probability”, Philosophy of Science, 34(4): 305–310. doi:10.1086/288168 (Scholar)
- Schervish, Mark J., Teddy Seidenfeld, and Joseph B. Kadane, 2012, “Measures of Incoherence: How Not to Gamble If You Must, with Discussion”, in José Bernardo, A. Phlip Dawid, James O. Berger, Mike West, David Heckerman, M.J. Bayarri, & Adrian F. M. Smith (eds.), Bayesian Statistics 7: Proceedings of the 7th Valencia International Meeting, Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp. 385–402. (Scholar)
- Schick, Frederic, 1986, “Dutch Bookies and Money Pumps”, Journal of Philosophy, 83(2): 112–119. doi:10.2307/2026054 (Scholar)
- Schmitt, Michael, and Laura Martignon, 2006, “On the Complexity of Learning Lexicographic Strategies”, Journal of Machine Learning Research, 7(Jan): 55–83. [Schmitt & Martignon 2006 available online] (Scholar)
- Schooler, Lael J. and Ralph Hertwig, 2005, “How Forgetting Aids Heuristic Inference”, Psychological Review, 112(3): 610–628. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.112.3.610 (Scholar)
- Seidenfeld, Teddy, Mark J. Schervish, and Joseph B. Kadane, 1995, “A Representation of Partially Ordered Preferences”, The Annals of Statistics, 23(6): 2168–2217. doi:10.1214/aos/1034713653 (Scholar)
- –––, 2012, “What Kind of Uncertainty Is That? Using Personal Probability for Expressing One’s Thinking about Logical and Mathematical Propositions”, Journal of Philosophy, 109(8–9): 516–533. doi:10.5840/jphil20121098/925 (Scholar)
- Selten, Reinhard, 1998, “Aspiration Adaptation Theory”, Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 42(2–3): 191–214. doi:10.1006/jmps.1997.1205 (Scholar)
- Simon, Herbert A., 1947, Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organization, first edition, New York: Macmillan. (Scholar)
- –––, 1955a, “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69(1): 99–118. doi:10.2307/1884852 (Scholar)
- –––, 1955b, “On a Class of Skew Distribution Functions”, Biometrika, 42(3–4): 425–440. doi:10.1093/biomet/42.3-4.425 (Scholar)
- –––, 1957a, Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organization, second edition, New York: Macmillan. (Scholar)
- –––, 1957b, Models of Man, New York: John Wiley. (Scholar)
- –––, 1976, “From Substantive to Procedural Rationality”, in 25 Years of Economic Theory, T. J. Kastelein, S. K. Kuipers, W. A. Nijenhuis, and G. R. Wagenaar (eds.), Boston, MA: Springer US, 65–86. doi:10.1007/978-1-4613-4367-7_6 (Scholar)
- Skyrms, Brian, 2003, The Stag Hunt and the Evolution of Social Structure, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9781139165228 (Scholar)
- Sorensen, Roy A., 1991, “Rationality as an Absolute Concept”, Philosophy, 66(258): 473–486. doi:10.1017/s0031819100065128 (Scholar)
- Spirtes, Peter, 2010, “Introduction to Causal Inference”, Journal of Machine Learning Research, 11(May): 1643–1662. [Spirtes 2010 available online] (Scholar)
- Stalnaker, Robert, 1991, “The Problem of Logical Omniscience, I”, Synthese, 89(3): 425–440. doi:10.1007/bf00413506 (Scholar)
- Stanovich, Keith E. and Richard F. West, 2000, “Individual Differences in Reasoning: Implications for the Rationality Debate?” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 23(5): 645–65. (Scholar)
- Stein, Edward, 1996, Without Good Reason: The Rationality Debate in Philosophy and Cognitive Science, Oxford: Clarendon Press. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780198237730.001.0001 (Scholar)
- Stevens, Jeffrey R., Jenny Volstorf, Lael J. Schooler, and Jörg Rieskamp, 2011, “Forgetting Constrains the Emergence of Cooperative Decision Strategies”, Frontiers in Psychology, 1: article 235. doi:10.3389/fpsyg.2010.00235 (Scholar)
- Stigler, George J., 1961, “The Economics of Information”, Journal of Political Economy, 69(3): 213–225. doi:10.1086/258464 (Scholar)
- Tarski, Alfred, Andrzej Mostowski, and Raphael M. Robinson, 1953, Undecidable Theories, Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co. (Scholar)
- Thaler, Richard H., 1980, “Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 1(1): 39–60. doi:10.1016/0167-2681(80)90051-7 (Scholar)
- Thaler, Richard H. and Cass R. Sustein, 2008, Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness, New Haven: Yale University Press. (Scholar)
- Todd, Peter M. and Geoffrey F. Miller, 1999, “From Pride and Prejudice to Persuasion: Satisficing in Mate Search”, in Gigerenzer et al. 1999: 287–308. (Scholar)
- Todd, Peter M., Gerd Gigerenzer, and ABC Research Group (eds.), 2012, Ecological Rationality: Intelligence in the World, New York: Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195315448.001.0001 (Scholar)
- Trivers, Robert L., 1971, “The Evolution of Reciprocal Altruism”, The Quarterly Review of Biology, 46(1): 35–57. doi:10.1086/406755 (Scholar)
- Trommershäuser, Julia, Laurence T. Maloney, and Michael S. Landy, 2003, “Statistical Decision Theory and Trade-Offs in the Control of Motor Response”, Spatial Vision, 16(3–4): 255–275. doi:10.1163/156856803322467527 (Scholar)
- Turner, Brandon M., Christian A. Rodriguez, Tony M. Norcia, Samuel M. McClure, and Mark Steyvers, 2016, “Why More Is Better: Simultaneous Modeling of EEG, FMRI, and Behavioral Data”, NeuroImage, 128(March): 96–115. doi:10.1016/j.neuroimage.2015.12.030 (Scholar)
- Tversky, Amos, 1969, “Intransitivity of Preferences”, Psychological Review, 76(1): 31–48. doi:10.1037/h0026750 (Scholar)
- Tversky, Amos and Daniel Kahneman, 1973, “Availability: A Heuristic for Judging Frequency and Probability”, Cognitive Psychology, 5(2): 207–232. doi:10.1016/0010-0285(73)90033-9 (Scholar)
- –––, 1974, “Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases”, Science, 185(4157): 1124–1131. doi:10.1126/science.185.4157.1124 (Scholar)
- –––, 1977, Causal Schemata in Judgments Under Uncertainty (No. TR-1060-77-10), Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency (DARPA). (Scholar)
- –––, 1981, “The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice”, Science, 211(4481): 483–458. doi:10.1126/science.7455683 (Scholar)
- –––, 1983, “Extensional Versus Intuitive Reasoning: The Conjunction Fallacy in Probability Judgment”, Psychological Review, 90(4): 293–315. doi:10.1037/0033-295x.90.4.293 (Scholar)
- –––, 1992, “Advances in Prospect Theory: Cumulative Representation of Uncertainty”, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4): 297–323. doi:10.1007/bf00122574 (Scholar)
- Vranas, Peter B.M., 2000, “Gigerenzer’s Normative Critique of Kahneman and Tversky”, Cognition, 76(3): 179–193. doi:10.1016/s0010-0277(99)00084-0 (Scholar)
- Wakker, Peter P., 2010, Prospect Theory: For Risk and Ambiguity, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9780511779329 (Scholar)
- Waldmann, Michael R., Keith J. Holyoak, and Angela Fratianne, 1995, “Causal Models and the Acquisition of Category Structure.”, Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 124(2): 181–206. doi:10.1037/0096-3445.124.2.181 (Scholar)
- Walley, Peter, 1991, Statistical Reasoning with Imprecise Probabilities, London: Chapman; Hall. (Scholar)
- Weber, Max, 1905, The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, London: Allen; Unwin. (Scholar)
- Wheeler, Gregory, 2004, “A Resource Bounded Default Logic”, in James Delgrande & Torsten Schaub (eds.), 10th International Workshop on Non-Monotonic Reasoning (Nmr 2004), Whistler, Canada, pp. 416–422. (Scholar)
- –––, 2017, “Machine Epistemology and Big Data”, in Lee McIntyre & Alex Rosenberg (eds.), The Routledge Companion to Philosophy of Social Science, Routledge, pp. 321–329. (Scholar)
- White, D. J., 1986, “Epsilon Efficiency”, Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 49(2): 319–337. doi:10.1007/bf00940762 (Scholar)
- Yechiam, Eldad and Guy Hochman, 2014, “Loss Attention in a Dual-Task Setting”, Psychological Science, 25(2): 494–502. doi:10.1177/0956797613510725 (Scholar)
- Yule, G. Udny, 1925, “A Mathematical Theory of Evolution, Based on the Conclusions of Dr. J. C. Williss, F.R.S.”, Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London. Series B, Containing Papers of a Biological Character, 213(402–410): 21–87. doi:10.1098/rstb.1925.0002 (Scholar)
- Zaffalon, Marco and Enrique Miranda, 2017, “Axiomatising Incomplete Preferences through Sets of Desirable Gambles”, Journal of Artificial Intelligence Research, 60(December): 1057–1126. doi:10.1613/jair.5230 (Scholar)