Linked bibliography for the SEP article "Convention" by Michael Rescorla
This is an automatically generated and experimental page
If everything goes well, this page should display the bibliography of the aforementioned article as it appears in the Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, but with links added to PhilPapers records and Google Scholar for your convenience. Some bibliographies are not going to be represented correctly or fully up to date. In general, bibliographies of recent works are going to be much better linked than bibliographies of primary literature and older works. Entries with PhilPapers records have links on their titles. A green link indicates that the item is available online at least partially.
This experiment has been authorized by the editors of the Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy. The original article and bibliography can be found here.
- Alston, William, 2000. Illocutionary Acts and Sentence Meaning, Ithaca: Cornell University Press. (Scholar)
- Anderson, Elizabeth, 2000. “Beyond Homo Economicus: New Developments in Theories of Social Norms,” Philosophy and Public Affairs, 29: 170–200. (Scholar)
- Aristotle, 1980. Nicomachean Ethics, trans. David Ross. Rev. trans. J. L. Ackrill and J. O. Urmson. Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1984. De Interpretatione,
in The Complete Works of Aristotle, ed. Jonathan
Barnes, Princeton: Princeton University Press. (Scholar)
- Aumann, Robert, 1974. “Subjectivity and Correlation in
Randomized Strategies,” Journal of Mathematical
Economics, 1: 67–96. (Scholar)
- –––, 1976. “Agreeing to Disagree,”
Annals of Statistics, 4: 1236–1239. (Scholar)
- –––, 1987. “Correlated Equilibrium as an
Expression of Bayesian Rationality,” Econometrica, 55:
1–18. (Scholar)
- Avramides, Anita, 1997. “Intention and Convention,” in A Companion to the Philosophy of Language, ed. Bob Hale and Crispin Wright, Malden: Blackwell. (Scholar)
- Ayer, A. J., 1936/1952. Language, Truth, and Logic, 2nd ed., New York: Dover. (Scholar)
- Axelrod, Robert, 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation, New York: Basic Books. (Scholar)
- Ben-Menahem, Yemima, 2006. Conventionalism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- Bennett, Jonathan, 1976. Linguistic Behavior, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- Bicchieri, Cristina, 2006. The Grammar of Society, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 2016. Norms in the Wild: How to Diagnose, Measure, and Change Social Norms, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Binmore, Ken, 2008. “Do Conventions Need to be Common Knowledge?” Topoi, 27: 17–27. (Scholar)
- Binmore, Ken and Samuelson, Larry, 2006. “The Evolution of
Focal Points,” Games and Economic Behavior, 55:
21–42. (Scholar)
- Blackburn, Simon, 1984. Spreading the Word, Oxford: Clarendon Press. (Scholar)
- Brandom, Robert, 1994. Making it Explicit, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. (Scholar)
- Brown, George, 1951. “Iterative Solutions to Games by
Fictitious Play,” in Activity Analysis of Production and
Allocation, ed. T. C. Koopmans, New York: Wiley. (Scholar)
- Bruner, Justin, O’Connor, Cailin, Rubin, Hannah, and Huttegger,
Simon, 2018. “David Lewis in the Lab: Experimental Results on
the Emergence of Meaning,” Synthese, 195:
603–621. (Scholar)
- Bunzl, Martin and Kreuter, Richard, 2003. “Conventions Made too Simple?”. Philosophy of the Social Sciences 33: 417–426. (Scholar)
- Burge, Tyler, 1975. “On Knowledge and Convention,” Philosophical Review, 84: 249–255. (Scholar)
- Carnap, Rudolf, 1937/2002. The Logical Syntax of Language. trans. Amethe Smeaton. Chicago: Open Court Press. (Scholar)
- Chomsky, Noam, 1980. Rules and Representations, New York: Columbia University Press. (Scholar)
- Coffa, Alberto, 1993. The Semantic Tradition from Kant to
Carnap, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- Cubitt, Robin, and Sugden, Robert, 2003. “Common Knowledge,
Salience, and Convention: A Reconstruction of David Lewis’s Game
Theory,” Economics and Philosophy, 19:
175–210. (Scholar)
- Davidson, Donald, 1984. “Convention and
Communication,” in
Inquiries into Truth and Interpretation, Oxford: Oxford
University Press. (Scholar)
- Davies, Martin, 2003. “Philosophy of Language,” in The Blackwell Companion to Philosophy, ed. Nicholas Bunnin and E. P. Tsui-James, Malden: Blackwell. (Scholar)
- Davis, Wayne, 2003. Meaning, Expression, and Thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- DiSalle, Robert, 2002. “Conventionalism and Modern Physics: A Reassessment,” Noûs, 36: 169–200. (Scholar)
- Dummett, Michael, 1991. The Logical Basis of Metaphysics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1993. The Seas of Language, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Einheuser, Iris, 2006. “Counterconventional Conditionals,” Philosophical Studies, 127: 459–482. (Scholar)
- Foster, Dean and Young, H. Peyton, 2001. “On the
Impossibility of Predicting the Behavior of Rational
Agents,” Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences, 98: 12848–12853. (Scholar)
- –––, 2003. “Learning, Hypothesis Testing,
and Nash equilibrium,” Games and Economics Behavior,
45: 73–96. (Scholar)
- –––, 2006. “Regret Testing: Learning to
Play Nash Equilibrium Without Knowing that You Have an
Opponent,” Theoretical Economics, 1:
341–367. (Scholar)
- Franssen, Maarten, 2004. “Review of Peter Vanderschraaf’s
Learning, and Coordination: Inductive Deliberation, Equilibrium,
and Convention,” Economics and Philosophy, 20:
375–416. (Scholar)
- Friedlin, M. I., and Wentzell, A. D., 1984. Random
perturbations of dynamical systems, New York: Springer. (Scholar)
- Friedman, Michael, 1983. Foundations of Space-Time Theories, Princeton: Princeton University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1999. Reconsidering Logical Positivism, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- Fudenberg, Drew and Levine, David, 1998. The Theory of
Learning in Games, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. (Scholar)
- Gauthier, David, 1979. “David Hume: Contractarian,” Philosophical Review, 88: 3–38. (Scholar)
- Gilbert, Margaret, 1981. “Game Theory and Convention,” Synthese, 46: 41–93. (Scholar)
- –––, 1983. “Agreements, Conventions, and Language,” Synthese, 54: 375–407. (Scholar)
- –––, 1983. “Notes on the Concept of Social Convention,” New Literary History, 14: 225–251. (Scholar)
- –––, 1989. On Social Facts, New York: Routledge. (Scholar)
- –––, 1990. “Rationality, Coordination, and Convention,” Synthese, 84: 1–21. (Scholar)
- –––, 2008. “Social Convention Revisited,” Topoi, 27: 5–16. (Scholar)
- Gödel, Kurt, 1995. “Is Mathematics Syntax of Language?”. In Kurt Gödel: Collected Works, vol. 3., ed. Solomon Feferman, John Dawson, Warren Goldfarb, Charles Parsons, and Robert Solovay, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Goldfarb, Warren, 1995. “Introductory Note to [Gödel
1995],” in Kurt Gödel: Collected Works,
vol. 3. ed. Solomon Feferman, John Dawson, Warren Goldfarb, Charles
Parsons, and Robert Solovay, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1997. “Semantics in Carnap: A Rejoinder to Coffa,” Philosophical Topics, 25: 51–66. (Scholar)
- Goldfarb, Warren and Ricketts, Thomas, 1992. “Carnap and the Philosophy of Mathematics,” in Science and Subjectivity, ed. David Bell and Wilhelm Vossenkuhl, Berlin: Akademie. (Scholar)
- Goodman, Nelson, 1976. Languages of Art, Indianapolis: Hackett. (Scholar)
- –––, 1978. Ways of Worldmaking, Indianapolis: Hackett. (Scholar)
- –––, 1989. “Just the Facts,
Ma’am!”. In
Relativism: Interpretation and Confrontation, ed.
Michael Krausz, Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press. (Scholar)
- Goyal, Sanjeev, and Janssen, Maarten, 1996. “Can We Rationally Learn to Coordinate?”. Theory and Decision, 40: 29–49. (Scholar)
- Grandy, Richard, 1977. “A Review of Lewis’s Convention:
A Philosophy Study,” Journal of Philosophy, 74:
129–139. (Scholar)
- Grünbaum, Adolf, 1962. “Geometry, Chronometry, and Empiricism,” in Minnesota Studies in the Philosophy of Science, vol. 3. Eds. Herbert Feigl and Grover Maxwell. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. (Scholar)
- Harman, Gilbert, 1996. “Moral Relativism,” in Moral Relativism and Moral Objectivity, ed. Gilbert Harman and J.J. Thompson, Cambridge: Blackwell. (Scholar)
- Harsanyi, John, and Selten, Reinhard, 1988. A General Theory
of Equilibrium Selection, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. (Scholar)
- Hawthorne, John, 1990. “A Note on ‘Languages and
Language.’” Australasian Journal of Philosophy,
68: 116–118. (Scholar)
- –––, 1993. “Meaning and Evidence: A Reply to Lewis,” Australasian Journal of Philosophy, 71: 206–211. (Scholar)
- Higginbotham, James, 1986. “Linguistic Theory and Davidson’s
Program in Semantics,” in Truth and Interpretation,
ed. Ernest Lepore. New York: Blackwell. (Scholar)
- Hume, David, 1740/1976. A Treatise of Human Nature, ed. L. A. Selby-Brigge, revised 3rd edn., ed. P. H. Nidditch, Oxford: Clarendon Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1777/ 1975. Enquiries Concerning Human Understanding and Concerning the Principles of Morals, ed. by L. A. Selby-Brigge, revised 3rd edn., ed. P. H. Nidditch, Oxford: Clarendon Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1741–2/1985. “Of the Original
Contract,” in Essays Moral, Political, and Literary,
ed. Eugene Miller, New York: Liberty Press.
- –––, 1752/1994. “Of Money,” in Hume: Political Essays, ed. Knud Haakonssen, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- Huttegger, Simon, 2014. “How Much Rationality Do We Need to Explain Conventions?” Philosophy Compass, 9: 11–21. (Scholar)
- Jamieson, Dale, 1975. “David Lewis on Convention,” Canadian Journal of Philosophy, 5: 73–81. (Scholar)
- Kalai, Ehud, and Lehrer, Ehud, 1993. “Rational Learning
Leads to Nash Equilibrium,” Econometrica, 61:
1019–45. (Scholar)
- Kandori, Michihiro, Mailath, George, and Rob, Rafael, 1993.
“Learning, Mutation, and Long-Run Equilibria in Games,”
Econometrica, 61: 29–56. (Scholar)
- Kölbel, Max, 1998. “Lewis, Language, Lust, and Lies,” Inquiry, 41: 301–315. (Scholar)
- Larson, Richard and Segal, Gabriel, 1995. Knowledge of Meaning, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. (Scholar)
- Laurence, Stephen, 1996. “A Chomskian Alternative to Convention-Based Semantics,” Mind, 105: 269–301. (Scholar)
- Lepore, Ernie, and Stone, Matthew, 2015. Imagination and Convention, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Lewis, David, 1969. Convention, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1975/1983. “Languages and Language,” Reprinted in Philosophical Papers, vol. 1. Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1976/2000. “Convention: Reply to Jamieson,” Reprinted in Papers in Ethics and Social Philosophy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1992/2000. “Meaning Without Use: Reply to Hawthorne,” Reprinted in Papers in Ethics and Social Philosophy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- Loar, Brian, 1976. “Two Theories of Meaning,”
in Truth and Meaning, ed. Gareth Evans and John
McDowell, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Locke, John, 1689/1975. An Essay Concerning the Human
Understanding, ed. Peter Nidditch, Oxford: Clarendon Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1689/1988. Two Treatises of Government, ed. Peter Laslett, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- Marmor, Andrei, 1996. “On Convention,” Synthese, 107: 349–371. (Scholar)
- –––, 2007. “Deep Conventions. ” Philosophy and Phenomenological Research, 74: 586–610. (Scholar)
- –––, 2009. Social Conventions, Princeton: Princeton University Press. (Scholar)
- Maynard Smith, John, and Price, George, 1973. “The Logic of
Animal Conflicts,” Nature, 146: 15–18. (Scholar)
- Milgrom, Paul, and Robert, John, 1991. “Adaptive and
Sophisticated Learning in Normal Form Games,” Games and
Economics Behavior, 3: 82–100. (Scholar)
- Miller, Seumas, 1986a. “Truthtelling and the Actual Language Relation,” Philosophical Studies, 49: 281–94. (Scholar)
- –––, 1986b. “Conventions, Interdependence of Action, and Collective Ends,” Nous, 20: 117–140. (Scholar)
- –––, 1990. “Rationalizing Conventions,” Synthese, 84: 23–41. (Scholar)
- –––, 2001. Social Action: A Teleological Account. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- Millikan, Ruth, 2005. Language: A Biological Model, Oxford: Clarendon Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 2008. “A Difference of Some Consequence Between Conventions and Rules,” Topoi, 27: 87–99. (Scholar)
- Moore, Richard, 2013. “Imitation and Conventional Communication,” Biology and Philosophy, 28: 481–500. (Scholar)
- Murphy, Liam and Nagel, Thomas, 2002. The Myth of Ownership, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Nachbar, John, 1997. “Prediction, Optimization, and Learning
in Repeated Games,”
Econometrica, 65: 275–309. (Scholar)
- Oddie, Graham, 1999. “Moral Realism, Moral Relativism, and Moral Rules,” Synthese, 117: 251–274. (Scholar)
- Parfit, Derek, 1984. Reasons and Persons, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Peacocke, Christopher, 1987. “Understanding Logical
Constants: A Realist’s Account,”
Proceedings of the British Academy, 73: 153–200. (Scholar)
- –––, 1998. “Concepts Without Words,” in Language, Thought, and Logic: Essays in Honor of Michael Dummett, ed. Richard Heck, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Plato, “Cratylus,” trans. C. D. C. Reeve. In Complete Works, ed. John Cooper, Indianapolis: Hackett, 1997. (Scholar)
- Poincaré, Henri, 1902/1905. Science and Hypothesis. In The Foundations of Science, trans. George Halsted, New York: The Science Press. (Scholar)
- Prawitz, Dag, 1977. “Meaning and Proofs: On the Conflict Between Classical and Intuitionistic Logic,” Theoria, 43: 2–40. (Scholar)
- Putnam, Hilary, 1962/1985. “The Analytic and the Synthetic,” Reprinted in Philosophical Papers, vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1962/1975. “An Examination of
Grünbaum’s Philosophy of Geometry,” Reprinted in
Philosophical Papers, vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1974/1985. “The Refutation of Conventionalism,” Reprinted in Philosophical Papers, vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1981. “Convention: A Theme in
Philosophy,” New Literary History, 13: 1–14. (Scholar)
- –––, 1987. The Many Faces of Realism, LaSalle: Open Court. (Scholar)
- Quine, W. V., 1936/1976. “Truth by Convention,” reprinted in The Ways of Paradox, 2nd ed., Cambridge: Harvard University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1963/1975. “Carnap and Logical Truth,” Reprinted The Ways of Paradox, 2nd ed., Cambridge: Harvard University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1969. “Foreword,” in Lewis,
1969. (Scholar)
- Rawls, John, 1955. “Two Concepts of Rules,” Philosophical Review, 63: 3–32. (Scholar)
- Reichenbach, Hans, 1922/1978. “The Present State of the Discussion on Relativity,” trans. M. Reichenbach. In Hans Reichenbach: Selected Writings, 1909–1953, vol. 2, Dordrecht: Reidel. (Scholar)
- Russell, Bertrand, 1921. The Analysis of Mind, London: Unwin Brothers Ltd. (Scholar)
- Samuelson, Larry, 1997. Evolutionary Games and Equilibrium
Selection, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. (Scholar)
- Schelling, Thomas, 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. (Scholar)
- Schiffer, Stephen, 1972. Meaning, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1987. Remnants of Meaning, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1993. “Actual-Language Relations,” Philosophical Perspectives, 7: 231–258. (Scholar)
- –––, 2006. “Two Perspectives on Knowledge of Language,” Philosophical Issues, 16: 275–287. (Scholar)
- –––, 2017. “Intention and Convention in
the Theory of Meaning,” in B. Hale, C. Wright, and A. Miller
(eds.), A Companion to the Philosophy of Language, 2nd
edition, Malden, MA: Wiley. (Scholar)
- Schlick, Moritz, 1917/1920. Space and Time in Contemporary Physics, trans. H. L. Brose. Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1953.“Are Natural Laws
Conventions?”. trans. Herbert Feigl and May Brodbeck. In
Readings in the Philosophy of Science, ed. Feigl and
Brodbeck, New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts. (Scholar)
- Schotter, Andrew, 1981. The Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- Searle, John, 1969. Speech Acts, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1995. The Construction of Social Reality, New York: Free Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 2001. Rationality in Action, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. (Scholar)
- Sellars, Wilfrid, 1963. “Some Reflections on Language Games,” Reprinted in Science, Perception, and Reality, New York: Routledge and Kegan Paul. (Scholar)
- Shapley, Lloyd, 1964. “Some Topics in Two-person
Games,”
Advances in Game Theory: Annals of Mathematical Studies, 5:
1–28. (Scholar)
- Shin, Hyun Song and Williamson, Timothy, 1996. “How Much Common Belief is Necessary for Convention?”. Games and Economic Behavior, 13: 252–268. (Scholar)
- Sidelle, Alan, 1989. Necessity, Essence, and Individuation: A Defense of Conventionalism, Cornell: Cornell University Press. (Scholar)
- Sider, Theodore, 2003. “Reductive Theories of Modality,” in The Oxford Handbook of Metaphysics, ed. Michael Loux and Dean Zimmerman, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Sillari, Giacomo, 2005. “A Logical Framework for Convention,” Synthese, 147: 379–400. (Scholar)
- –––, 2008. “Common Knowledge and Convention,” Topoi, 27: 29–39. (Scholar)
- Simmel, Georg, 1908/1971. “How is Society Possible?”. Reprinted in George Simmel: On Individuality and Social Forms, ed. Donald Levine, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. (Scholar)
- Sklar, Lawrence, 1977. Space, Time, and Spacetime. Berkeley: University of California Press. (Scholar)
- Skyrms, Brian, 1996. Evolution of the Social Contract. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 1998. “Salience and Symmetry-Breaking in the Evolution of Convention,” Law and Philosophy, 17: 411–418. (Scholar)
- –––, 2010. Signals: Evolution, Learning, and Communication, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Snare, Francis, 1991. Moral, Motivation, and Convention. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Scholar)
- Sugden, Robert, 1986/2004. The Economics of Rights,
Co-operation, and Welfare, 2nd ed., New York: Palgrave
Macmillan. (Scholar)
- –––, 1998. “The Role of Inductive Reasoning in the Evolution of Conventions,” Law and Philosophy, 17: 377–410. (Scholar)
- –––, 2011. “Salience, Inductive Reasoning,
and the Emergence of Conventions,” Journal of Economic
Behavior and Organization, 79: 35–47. (Scholar)
- Syverson, Paul, 2003. Logic, Convention, and Common Knowledge: A Conventionalist Account of Logic, Stanford: CSLI Publications. (Scholar)
- Taylor, Peter and Jonker, Leo, 1978. “Evolutionarily Stable
Strategies and Game Dynamics,” Mathematical
Biosciences, 40: 145–156. (Scholar)
- Ullmann-Margalit, Edna, 1977. The Emergence of Norms. Oxford: Clarendon Press. (Scholar)
- Vanderschraaf, Peter, 1995. “Convention as Correlated Equilibrium,” Erkenntnis, 42: 65–87. (Scholar)
- –––, 1998a. “The Informal Game Theory in
Hume’s Account of Convention,” Economics and
Philosophy, 14: 215–247. (Scholar)
- –––, 1998b. “Knowledge, Equilibrium, and Convention,” Erkenntnis, 49: 337–369. (Scholar)
- –––, 2001. Learning and Coordination: Inductive Deliberation, Equilibrium, and Convention, London: Routledge. (Scholar)
- Verbeek, Bruno, 2008. “Conventions and Moral Norms: The Legacy of Lewis,” Topoi, 27: 73–86. (Scholar)
- Warren, Jared, 2015. “Conventionalism, Consistency, and Consistency Sentences,” Synthese, 192: 1351–1371. (Scholar)
- –––, 2017. “Revisiting Quine on Truth by Convention,” Journal of Philosophical Logic, 46: 119–139. (Scholar)
- Williams, Bernard, 2002. Truth and Truthfulness, Princeton: Princeton University Press. (Scholar)
- Williamson, Timothy, 2000. Knowledge and its Limits. Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Young, H, Peyton. 1993. “The Evolution of
Conventions,”
Econometrica, 61: 57–84. (Scholar)
- –––, 1996. “The Economics of
Convention,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10:
105–122. (Scholar)
- –––, 1998. Individual Strategy and Social
Structure, Princeton: Princeton University Press. (Scholar)
- –––, 2004. Strategic Learning and its Limits, Oxford: Oxford University Press. (Scholar)
- Zermelo, Ernst, 1913. “Über eine Anwendung der
Mengenlehre auf die theorie des Schachspiels,” Proceedings
of the Fifth International Congress of Mathematicians, 2:
501–4. (Scholar)