Skip to main content
Log in

The political process of the revolutionary samurai: a comparative reconsideration of Japan’s Meiji Restoration

  • Published:
Theory and Society Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the 1860s and 1870s, the feudal monarchy of the Tokugawa shogunate, which had ruled Japan for over two centuries, was overthrown, and the entire political order it had commanded was dismantled. This immense political transformation, comparable in its results to the great social revolutions of the seventeenth through nineteenth centuries in the West, was distinctive for lacking a major role for mass political mobilization. Since popular political action was decisive elsewhere for both providing the force for social revolutions to defeat old regimes and for pushing revolutionary leaders to more radical policies, the Meiji Restoration’s combination of revolutionary outcomes with conservative personnel and means is puzzling. This article argues that previous accounts fail to explain why a group of relatively low-status samurai—administrative functionaries with some hereditary political privileges but in fact little secure power within the old regime—was able to overcome far more deeply entrenched political actors. To explain this, it is necessary to distinguish clearly between two political processes: the long-standing political relations of feudal monarchy and magnate lords and the unprecedented emergence of independent samurai political action and organizations cutting across domain boundaries. It was the interaction of these two processes that produced the overthrow of the Tokugawa and enabled the revolutionary outcomes that followed it. This article’s revised explanation of the Meiji Restoration clearly places it within the same theoretical parameters as the major revolutions of the seventeenth century and later.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In this article, names are given in the traditional Japanese order of family name first. I also follow the historiographical convention of referring to major lords by their personal names, to avoid confusion of the various Tokugawas, Matsudairas, and so on.

  2. The narrative of this paragraph is based on Jansen (1961, pp. 143–50).

  3. There is no good analogy in European history for the coexistence of emperor and feudal monarchy in Japan from the late twelfth century to 1868. This situation was the product of the slow decay of the power of the imperial regime in Kyoto over aristocratic houses and provincial warriors, and the feudal monarchical dynasties (beginning with the Kamakura shogunate) arose to maintain some kind of order among the warriors who increasingly controlled the land in fact if not in law. The supremacy of the feudal monarchy over the imperial court was practically absolute during most of the Tokugawa period.

  4. Of course, this formula, like the French formula of the three estates of clergy, nobility and commoners, paints an incomplete and misleading picture of the social structure, even if it is not entirely inaccurate.

  5. Particularly evocative of this near unanimity is Tōyama’s conversion to the dominant view. The first (1951) edition of his landmark synthetic account of the Restoration argued that the “template” for the Meiji state (i.e., an alliance among lower-status samurai, commoner landlords, and a mercantile bourgeoisie) had been established in Japan in the 1830s–1840s, but this argument received so much criticism that the second (1972) edition removed almost all references to this hypothesis and instead emphasized the decisive role of the foreign threat.

  6. The term “feudal monarchy” is the most accurate and informative term for what the Tokugawa shogunate was because of these two characteristics. To put it another way, it fiscally “lived off its own,” and its rule over the majority of Japan’s territory and population passed through its personal authority over the magnate lords as overlord of the “warrior houses.”

  7. Against the potential accusation that this is a problematically functionalist argument, I would make two points. First, the claim here is not that the political order fulfills functions necessary for the maintenance of abstract entities such as society or the mode of production but instead that political institutions are functional for the interests of concrete groups of elites. Second, the embedding of elites in political institutions is much more direct in pre-capitalist political orders than in modern capitalist states, often extending to the point of the patrimonial appropriation of political powers (Ertman 1997; Adams 2005; Brenner 2007; Lachmann 2009). Thus, although conflicts are endemic (among factions of elites over the state, between the faction that controls the state and other elites), the mechanism linking the functioning of institutions and elites’ interests is relatively straightforward. I thank Richard Lachmann for alerting me to this objection.

  8. I would like to thank Richard Lachmann for suggesting I clarify this point.

  9. It should be noted that an equivalent value of (almost entirely domestic) debt was canceled by the central government on the basis of being too old or having been a de facto forced “contribution” that was never going to have been repaid anyway. The immense debts of the Tokugawa-era ruling class are sometimes described as evidence of the growing power of a mercantile bourgeoisie. However, making massive “loans” that can go decades without being repaid is a dubious sign of class power. In this respect, borrowing was taxation of merchant wealth by other means.

  10. It was quite common for houses without successors to adopt the younger sons of other magnate houses, and the ruling dynasty had several branch houses for precisely this purpose—the Tokugawa of Mito, Kii, and Owari, as well as three cadet lines with their own surnames, including the Hitotsubashi. Yoshinobu’s name is also often read as ‘Keiki’. He retook the surname Tokugawa when he was named heir to Tokugawa Iemochi in 1866.

  11. I would like to acknowledge an anonymous reviewer for suggesting the need to emphasize this point from the outset.

  12. Case studies on the loyalist movement in English include Brown (1981) on Fukuoka, Jansen (1961) on Tosa, Koschmann (1982) on Mito, and Huber (1981, 1982) on Chōshū and the brief loyalist control of Kyoto.

  13. Narratives of the formation of the militia (shotai) in Chōshū, the Chōshū civil war, the Satsuma-Chōshū alliance, and the failure of the feudal monarchy’s second expedition against Chōshū can be found in Craig (1961) and Huber (1981).

  14. It is worth noting in this context that the “loyalists” often took a quite cynical view of the politics of the imperial court, describing it as “theater” and the emperor himself as a “jewel” that they plotted to “steal” (Tōyama 1991a, p. 102).

  15. This interpretation is an alternative to the claim that the conflict was between more or less economically “dynamic” groups of landowners.

  16. The discussion here focuses on the comparison with the French Revolution so as to attempt to account for the relatively stark contrast with that case. However, it should be noted that in terms of the role of popular unrest and the organization of militias led by subordinate elites as part of the revolutionary movement, the Meiji Restoration is much closer to the English Civil War (Goldstone 1991b, pp. 403, 413).

  17. Japanese historians and some American historical sociologists make much of the focus on local targets and lack of broader political organization in Japanese peasant uprisings. However, these particular “weaknesses” (if one wants to call them that) also characterize the Great Fear (Doyle 1988, pp. 185–203).

  18. The ideological schema of revolutionary movements should not be assumed to be prior to or unconnected with their political means. According to Sewell (1996), the deputies of the National Assemblies in large part improvised the ideological schema of popular revolution only in response to, and in an attempt to regain the initiative from, the fact of effective popular mobilization following the taking of the Bastille.

  19. It is true that early twentieth-century Japan’s very gradual extension of the franchise and increase in parliamentary influence underwent a sharp reversal in the 1930s that was only overcome under the postwar Allied occupation (Scalapino 1953). However, the political history of France from Napoleon’s coup to the establishment of the Third Republic should encourage caution in labeling Japan’s trajectory as an exceptional case of “authoritarian capitalism” requiring a special explanation.

References

  • Adams, J. (2005). The familial state: Ruling families and merchant capitalism in early modern Europe. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allinson, J. C., & Anievas, A. (2010). The uneven and combined development of the Meiji Restoration: a passive revolutionary road to capitalist modernity. Capital & Class, 34(3), 469–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, P. (1974). Lineages of the absolutist state. New York: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoyama, T. (2011). Keiō 3-Nen 12-Gatsu 9-Ka no Seihen. In Meiji Restoration Historical Society (Ed.), Kōza Meiji Ishin 1: Bakumatsu Seiji to Shakai Hendō (pp. 218–250). Tokyo: Yūshisha.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beasley, W. G. (1972). The Meiji Restoration. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beasley, W. G. (1989). The foreign threat and the opening of the ports. In M. B. Jansen (Ed.), The Cambridge history of Japan, Volume 5: The nineteenth century (pp. 259–307). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bolitho, H. (1974). Treasures among men: The Fudai Daimyo in Tokugawa Japan. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolitho, H. (1989). The Tempō Crisis. In M. B. Jansen (Ed.), The Cambridge history of Japan, Volume 5: The nineteenth century (pp. 116–167). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bolitho, H. (1991). The Han. In J. W. Hall (Ed.), Cambridge history of Japan, Volume 4: Early modern Japan (pp. 183–234). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Brenner, R. (1993). Merchants and revolution. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brenner, R. (2007). Property and progress: Where Adam Smith went wrong. In C. Wickham (Ed.), Marxist history-writing for the twenty-first century (pp. 49–110). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, D. D. (1981). From Tempō to Meiji: Fukuoka Han in Late Tokugawa Japan. University of Hawaii PhD Dissertation.

  • Chibber, V. (2013). Postcolonial theory and the Specter of capital. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chizuka, T. (2001[1994]). Furansu Kakumei to Meiji Ishin. In A. Tanaka (Ed.) Sekai no naka no Meiji Ishin (pp. 157–74). Tokyo: Yoshikawakōbunkan.

  • Comninel, G. C. (1987). Rethinking the French Revolution. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Craig, A. M. (1961). Chōshū in the Meiji Restoration. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Craig, A. M. (1986). The central government. In M. B. Jansen & G. Rozman (Eds.), Japan in Transition, from Tokugawa to Meiji (pp. 36–67). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dore, R. P. (1984[1964]). Education in Tokugawa Japan. London: The Athlone Press.

  • Doyle, W. (1988). Origins of the French Revolution (2nd ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisenstadt, S. N. (1992). Frameworks of the great revolutions: culture, social structure, history and human agency. International Social Science Journal, 133, 385–402.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisenstadt, S. N. (1996). Japanese civilization: A comparative view. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ertman, T. (1997). Birth of the Leviathan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (1991a). Ideology, cultural frameworks, and the process of revolution. Theory and Society, 20(4), 405–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (1991b). Revolution and rebellion in the early modern world. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2014). Revolutions: A very short introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Harootunian, H. D. (1959). The progress of Japan and the Samurai class, 1868–1882. Pacific Historical Review, 28(3), 255–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harootunian, H. D. (1970). Toward restoration. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, T. M. (1981). The revolutionary origins of modern Japan. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, T. M. (1982). “Men of High Purpose” and the politics of direct action, 1862–1864. In T. Najita & J. V. Koschmann (Eds.), Conflict in modern Japanese history (pp. 107–127). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ikegami, E. (1995). The Taming of the Samurai. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ikegami, E. (2005). Bonds of civility. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iwaki, T. (2010). Kinai no Bakumatsu Shakai. In Meiji Restoration Historical Society (Ed.), Kōza Meiji Ishin 1: Bakumatsu Seiji to Shakai Hendō (pp. 184–217). Tokyo: Yūshisha.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jansen, M. B. (1961). Sakamoto Ryōma and the Meiji Restoration. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jansen, M. B. (1989). The Meiji Restoration. In M. B. Jansen (Ed.), The Cambridge history of Japan, Volume 5: The nineteenth century (pp. 308–366). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Koschmann, J. V. (1982). Action as a text: Ideology in the Tengu insurrection. In T. Najita & J. V. Koschmann (Eds.), Conflict in modern Japanese history (pp. 81–106). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, R. (1989). Elite conflict and state formation in 16th- and 17th-century England and France. American Sociological Review, 54(2), 141–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, R. (2009). Greed and contingency: state fiscal crises and imperial failure in early modern Europe. American Journal of Sociology, 115(1), 39–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levi, M. (1981). The predatory theory of rule. Politics and Society, 10(1), 431–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markoff, J. (2006[1995]). Violence, emancipation, and democracy: The Countryside and the French Revolution. In G. Kates (Ed.), The French Revolution: Recent debates and new controversies, 2nd ed. (pp. 165–197). New York: Routledge.

  • Miyamoto, M., Sakudō, Y., & Yasuba,Y. (1998[1965]). Economic development in preindustrial Japan, 1859–1894. In M. Smitka (Ed.), Japanese prewar growth (pp. 63–86). New York: Garland.

  • Moore, B., Jr. (1966). Social origins of dictatorship and democracy: Lord and peasant in the making of the modern world. Boston: Beacon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nakamura, M. (1992). Meiji Ishin no Sekaishi-teki Ichi: Itaria, Roshia, Nihon no Hikakushi. In M. Nakamura (Ed.), Nihon no Kindai to Shihonshugi (pp. 1–38). Tokyo: Tokyo University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norman, E. H. (1975). Japan’s emergence as a modern state. In J. W. Dower (Ed.), Origins of the modern Japanese state (pp. 109–316). New York: Pantheon Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nishikawa, S., & Amano, M. (2004). Domains and their economic policies. In A. Hayami, O. Saito, & R. P. Toby (Eds.), The economic history of Japan: 1600–1990, Volume 1: Emergence of economic society in Japan, 1600–1859 (pp. 247–267). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ōguchi, Y. (2004). The finances of the Tokugawa Shogunate. In A. Hayami, O. Saito, & R. P. Toby (Eds.), The economic history of Japan: 1600–1990, Volume 1: Emergence of economic society in Japan (pp. 192–212). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, L. S. (1998). Mercantilism in a Japanese domain. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Scalapino, R. (1953). Democracy and the party movement in prewar Japan. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sewell, W. H. (1996). Historical events as transformations of structures: inventing revolution at the Bastille. Theory and Society, 25(6), 841–881.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shibahara, T. (1977). Seikaishi no Naka no Meiji Ishin. Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skocpol, T. (1979). States and social revolutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, T. C. (1988[1961]). Japan’s Aristocratic Revolution. In Native sources of Japanese industrialization, 1750–1920 (pp. 133–147). Berkeley: University of California Press.

  • Soboul, A. (1974). The French Revolution, 1787–1799. London: Unwin Hyman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swale, A. D. (2009). The Meiji Restoration: Monarchism, mass communication and conservative revolution. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tackett, T. (1996). Becoming a revolutionary: The deputies of the French national assembly and the emergence of a revolutionary culture (1789–1790). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Takahashi, K. (2001[1953]). Nihon no Toshiseido-Shi ni Okeru Meiji Ishin no Ichi. In A. Tanaka (Ed.), Sekai no naka no Meiji Ishin (pp. 99–135). Tokyo: Yoshikawakōbunkan.

  • Totman, C. (1967). Politics in the Tokugawa Bakufu, 1600–1843. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Totman, C. (1980). The collapse of the Tokugawa Bakufu, 1862–1868. Honolulu: The University of Hawaii Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tōyama, S. (1991a[1951]). Meiji Ishin. In Tōyama Shigeki Chosakushū (pp. 3–203). Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten.

  • Tōyama, S. (1991b[1972]). Meiji Ishin = Burujoa Kakumei-Ron ni Tsuite: Topai-shi ni Kotaeru. In Tōyama Shigeki Chosakushū (pp. 286–98). Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten.

  • Tilly, C. (1985). War making and state making as organized crime. In P. Evans, D. Rueschemeyer, & T. Skocpol (Eds.), Bringing the state back in (pp. 170–191). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. (1992). Coercion, capital, and European States, AD 990–1992. Cambridge: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trimberger, E. K. (1978). Revolution from above. New Brunswick: Transaction Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Umegaki, M. (1986). From domain to prefecture. In M. B. Jansen & G. Rozman (Eds.), Japan in transition, from Tokugawa to Meiji (pp. 91–110). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vlastos, S. (1989). Opposition movements in early Meiji, 1868–1885. In M. B. Jansen (Ed.), The Cambridge history of Japan, Volume 5: The nineteenth century (pp. 367–431). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • White, J. W. (1988). State growth and popular protest in Tokugawa Japan. Journal of Japanese Studies, 14(1), 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, J. W. (1995). Ikki: Social conflict and political protest in early modern Japan. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank Vivek Chibber, Jeff Goodwin, Richard Lachmann, an anonymous reviewer for Theory and Society, and the participants of the NYU Economic and Political Sociology Workshop for their comments on earlier versions of this article.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mark Cohen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cohen, M. The political process of the revolutionary samurai: a comparative reconsideration of Japan’s Meiji Restoration. Theor Soc 43, 139–168 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-014-9215-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-014-9215-6

Keywords

Navigation