Skip to main content
Log in

A Few Good Companies: Rethinking Firms’ Responsibilities Toward Common Pool Resources

  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While a significant body of literature has highlighted the moral obligations of companies regarding the sustainable use of common pool resources, business activities that contribute to the sustenance of common pool resources remain embryonic. Studies in this area have largely focused on environmental stimuli rather than on the complex motivational structures that drive or hinder businesses’ contributions to common pool resources. We explore the different motives and behaviors of businesses and their contributions to common pool resources, and propose four roles by which companies’ motives and behaviors toward common pool resources can be categorized—namely, free riders, followers, believers, and altruists. We shift the focus from moral reasoning to Platt’s (Am Psychol 28(8):641–651, 1973) notion of social trapping and his “ways out” as Platt’s “ways out” include propositions that address not only environmental stimuli but also companies’ motives. Both types of propositions are important for businesses to be able to respond rapidly to the scarcity of certain common pool resources and to use and maintain common pool resources in a sustainable way. Based on our categorization and Platt’s typology of social traps and “ways out,” we propose a theoretical framework by which companies and other stakeholders are provided with a differentiating perspective that allows for propositions addressing the complex nature of motivational structures and common pool resources. Our framework helps business leaders, institutions, and policy makers decide on actions that can contribute to the sustainability of common pool resources and that differ from actions that solely serve organizational self-interests.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The original term used by Samuelson and Buchanan was “rivalry of consumption”; it was replaced by Ostrom and Ostrom (1977) with “subtractability of use.”

  2. “Another example is the decay of railroad service, as people begin to prefer using their cars. As the railroad begins to go downhill, still more people prefer cars. The process is self-accelerating, ending up with no one riding the trains, while there are traffic jams on the highways in which everyone involved would prefer—too late—to be using the railroad” (Platt 1973, p. 642).

  3. Platt (1973) used the Kitty Genovese murder in New York City as an example of a countertrap. In this example, a girl was raped and killed in an alley, with numerous neighbors watching from their homes without calling the police. Platt assumed that the neighbors’ lack of (re)action was due to their fear of the killer’s revenge. “Each observer may have felt a strong prick of social conscience at the time but simply hoped that someone else would make the troublesome phone call first” (Platt 1973, p. 641).

Abbreviations

UNEP:

United Nations Environmental Program

WCED:

World Commission on Environment and Development

References

  • Anderson, L., & Seijo, J. (2010). Bioeconomics of fisheries management. Ames, IA: Wiley-Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Badhwar, N. K. (1993). Altruism versus self-interest: Sometimes a false dichotomy. Social Philosophy and Policy, 10(01), 90–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brundtland, G. H. (1987). Report of the World Commission on Environment and Development: “Our common future”. New York, NY: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32(125), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bettignies, H. C., Lépineux, F., & de Lamartine, A. (2005). Should multinational corporations be concerned with the global common good? An interdisciplinary exploration. Fontainebleau: INSEAD Working Paper Series.

  • Donaldson, T. (1982). Corporations and morality (pp. 36–58). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drucker, P. (2010). The frontiers of management. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer-Kowalski, M., Swilling, M., von Weizsäcker, E. U., Ren, Y., Moriguchi, Y., Crane, W., et al. (2011). Decoupling natural resource use and environmental impacts from economic growth. Nairobi: United Nations Envrionmental Programme.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gröschl, S. (2013). Uncertainty, diversity and the common good: Changing norms and new leadership paradigms. Burlington: Gower Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162(3859), 1243–1248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jonsen, K., Tatli, A., Özbilgin, M., & Bell, M. (2013). The tragedy of the uncommons: Reframing workforce diversity. Human Relations, 66(2), 271–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khalil, E. L. (1990). Beyond self-interest and altruism. Economics and Philosophy, 6(2), 255–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lacy, P. (2013). The United Nations Global Compact—Accenture CEO study on sustainability 2013. New York, NY: United Nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leal Filho, W. (2000). Dealing with misconceptions on the concept of sustainability. International Journal of Sustainability in Higher Education, 1(1), 9–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • López, M. M., Garcia, A., & Rodriguez, L. (2007). Sustainable development and corporate performance: A study based on the Dow Jones Sustainability Index. Journal of Business Ethics, 75(3), 285–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milinski, M., Semmann, D., & Krambeck, H.-J. (2002). Reputation helps solve the ‘tragedy of the commons’. Nature, 415(6870), 424–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millennium Ecosystem Assessment Board. (2005). Ecosystems and human well-being: Synthesis report. Washington, DC: Island Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Narver, J. C., & Slater, S. F. (1990). The effect of a market orientation on business profitability. Journal of marketing, 54(4), 20–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, T. (2009). Reconsidering the common good in a business context. Journal of Business Ethics, 85(1), 25–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2008). Institutions and the environment. Economic Affairs, 28(3), 24–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. The American Economic Review, 100(3), 641–672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., Burger, J., Field, C., Norgaard, R., & Policansky, D. (1999). Revisiting the commons: Local lessons, global challenges. Science, 284(5412), 278–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V., & Ostrom, E. (1977). Public goods and public choices. In E. S. Savas (Ed.), Alternatives for delivering public services: Toward improved performance (pp. 7–49). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Platt, J. (1973). Social traps. American Psychologist, 28(8), 641–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. (1971). On the ecology of micromotives. Public Interest, 25, 61–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sison, A. J. G., & Fontrodona, J. (2006). The nature of the firm, agency theory and shareholder theory: A critique from philosophical anthropology. Journal of Business Ethics, 66(1), 33–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, B. F. (1963). Operant behavior. American Psychologist, 18(8), 503–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, B. F. (1969). Contingencies of reinforcement: A theoretical analysis. New York, NY: Appleton-Century-Crofts.

    Google Scholar 

  • Velasquez, M. (1992). International business, morality, and the common good. Business Ethics Quarterly, 2(1), 27–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments and suggestions to improve the quality of the paper. They are also grateful to Dr. Lepoutre and Dr. Shymko for their for their insightful comments on the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Patricia Gabaldon.

Additional information

Both authors have equally contributed to the development of the article.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gabaldon, P., Gröschl, S. A Few Good Companies: Rethinking Firms’ Responsibilities Toward Common Pool Resources. J Bus Ethics 132, 579–588 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-014-2361-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-014-2361-y

Keywords

Navigation