Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter December 3, 2013

In Defense of the Euro: An Austrian Perspective (With a Critique of the Errors of the ECB and the Interventionism of Brussels)

  • Jesús Huerta de Soto EMAIL logo

Abstract

Economists of the Austrian School are supporters of the gold standard because it hinders and restricts arbitrary policies and rulers: it disciplines the behavior of all the agents involved in the democratic process and encourages people to act orderly and morally. It is, in fact, an obstacle to the lies and demagoguery because it spreads and facilitates transparency and truth in social relations. The creation of the euro in 1999 and its final implementation in 2002 assumed the disappearance of monetary nationalism and flexible exchange rates in most of continental Europe. We will discuss the errors committed by the European Central Bank. It is now seen how the different states of the European Monetary Union have given and completely lost their monetary autonomy, that is to say the ability to manipulate their local currency to serve political needs. In this sense, the euro has therefore acted, at least for the countries of the euro area, very similar to that which was, in its time, the gold standard manner. This is why the euro should be considered a real equivalent, albeit imperfect, of the gold standard.

References

Anderson, B. M.1924. “Cheap Money, Gold, and the Federal Reserve Bank Policy.” Chase Economic Bulletin4(3):9.Search in Google Scholar

Bagus, P.2010. The Tragedy of the Euro. Auburn, AB: Ludwig von Mises Institute. (Madrid: Unión Editorial, 2011.)Search in Google Scholar

Balcerowicz, L.2010. “A More Perfect Monetary Union.” Project Syndicate, May 10.Search in Google Scholar

Barbieri, P.2012. “The Tragedy of Argentina.” The Wall Street Journal, April 20–22, p.15.Search in Google Scholar

Barro, R.2012. “An Exit Strategy from the Euro.” The Wall Street Journal, January 10, p.16.Search in Google Scholar

Blackstone, B., M.Karnitschnig, and R.Thomson. 2012. “Europe’s Banker Talks Tough: Draghi Says Continent’s Social Model Is ‘Gone,’ Won’t Backtrack on Austerity.” The Wall Street Journal Europe, February 24.Search in Google Scholar

Block, W.1999. “The Gold Standard: A Critique of Friedman, Mundell, Hayek and Greenspan from the Free Enterprise Perspective.” Managerial Finance25(5):1533.10.1108/03074359910765939Search in Google Scholar

Booth, P.2011. “Europe’s Single Market isn’t a Free Market.” The Wall Street Journal, Friday, December 23, p.17.Search in Google Scholar

Cabrillo, F.2012. “Encadenados al Euro.” Expansión, January 30, p.39.Search in Google Scholar

Eichengreen, B.2011. The Rise and the Fall of the Dollar and the Future of the International Monetary System. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Estefania, J.2011. “Constitución Antipática.” El País, December 12, p.29.Search in Google Scholar

Feldstein, M.2011. “The Euro Zone’s Double Failure.” The Wall Street Journal, December 16, p.17.Search in Google Scholar

Gallo, A.2012. “Trade Policy and Protectionism in Argentina.” Economic Affairs32(1):559.10.1111/j.1468-0270.2011.02129.xSearch in Google Scholar

Goolsbee, A.2011. “Europe’s Currency Road to Nowhere.” The Wall Street Journal, November 30, p.18.Search in Google Scholar

Gramm, P., and R. J.Taylor. 2012. “The Hidden Costs of Monetary Easing”. The Wall Street Journal, September 13, p.18.Search in Google Scholar

Hartwell, R. M.1995. A History of the Mont Pèlerin Society. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.Search in Google Scholar

Hayek, F. A.1971. Monetary Nationalism and International Stability. New York: Augustus M. Kelley. [First edition, London: Longmans, Green, 1937.]Search in Google Scholar

Hayek, F. A.1979. Unemployment and Monetary Policy: Government as Generator of the Business Cycle. San Francisco, CA: Cato Institute. Lecture given February 8, 1975 and entitled, “Inflation, the Misdirection of Labor, and Unemployment” at the Academia Nazionale dei Lincei in Rome in celebration of the 100th anniversary of Luigi Einaudi’s birth.Search in Google Scholar

Hollande, F.2012. “La Vía Conservadora de la Austeridad es Ineficaz y Peligrosa.” La Gaceta, January 26, p.1.Search in Google Scholar

Huerta de Soto, J.2003. “Nota Crítica sobre la Propuesta de Reforma de las Normas Internacionales de Contabilidad.” Partida Doble, no. 21, April,247.Search in Google Scholar

Huerta de Soto, J.2009. “The Fatal Error of Solvency II.” Economic Affairs29(2):747.10.1111/j.1468-0270.2009.01900.xSearch in Google Scholar

Huerta de Soto, J.2010. “Algunas Reflexiones Complementarias sobre la Crisis Económica y la Teoría del Ciclo.” Procesos de Mercado: Revista Europea de Economía Política7(2):193203.Search in Google Scholar

Huerta de Soto, J.2011. “Economic Recessions, Banking Reform and the Future of Capitalism.” Economic Affairs31(2):7684.10.1111/j.1468-0270.2011.02084.xSearch in Google Scholar

Huerta de Soto, J.2012. Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles, 3rd revised ed. Auburn, AB: Ludwig von Mises Institute. [First Spanish edition, 1998.]Search in Google Scholar

Issing, O.2008. The Birth of the Euro. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Krugman, P.2012a. “The Austerity Debacle.” The New York Times, January 29.Search in Google Scholar

Krugman, P.2012b. End This Depression Now. London and New York: W.W. Northton.Search in Google Scholar

Laperriere, A.2012. “The High Cost of the Fed’s Cheap Money.” The Wall Street Journal, March 6.Search in Google Scholar

Luskin, D. L., and L.Roche Kelly. 2012. “Europe’s Supply-Side Revolution.” The Wall Street Journal, February 20, p.17.Search in Google Scholar

Martín Ferrand, M.2012. “El Euro es la Solución.” ABC, April 13, p.14.Search in Google Scholar

Mises, L. von. 1966. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics, 3rd ed. Chicago: Henry Regnery.Search in Google Scholar

Mises, L. von. 1969. Omnipotent Government: The Rise of Total State and Total War. New Rochelle, NY: Arlington House.Search in Google Scholar

Mises, M. von. 1984. My Years with Ludwig Von Mises. Iowa: Center for Future Education.Search in Google Scholar

Mises, L. von. 2009. The Theory of Money and Credit. Auburn, AB: Ludwig von Mises Institute. [First German edition, 1912.]Search in Google Scholar

Mundell, R.1961. “Optimum Currency Areas.” The American Economic Review51:65764.Search in Google Scholar

O’Caithnia, B.2011. “Compounding Agricultural Poverty: How the EU’s Common Agricultural Policy Is Strangling European Recovery.” In Institutions in Crisis: European Perspectives on the Recession, edited by D.Howden, 20028. Cheltenham and Northampton: Edward Elgar.Search in Google Scholar

Skidelsky, R.2011. “The Keynes-Hayek Rematch.” August 19. La Vanguardia, October 6, p.21.Search in Google Scholar

Sorman, G.2011. “La Crisis del Euro no va a tener lugar.” ABC, October 30, p.54.Search in Google Scholar

Stiglitz, J.2012. “Después de la Austeridad”. El Pais, Negocios, May 13, p.19.Search in Google Scholar

Ulrich, F.2011. “Fiscal Stimulus, Financial Ruin.” In Institutions in Crisis: European Perspectives on the Recession, edited by D.Howden, 14263. Cheltenham and Northampton: Edward Elgar.Search in Google Scholar

Vidal-folch, X.2012. “Heroica Reconstrucción del Estado Fallido Griego.” El País, February 23, p.21.Search in Google Scholar

Whyte, J.2011. “The High Cost of a Cheap Pound.” The Wall Street Journal, May 17.Search in Google Scholar

  1. 1

    The main authors and theoretical formulations can be consulted in Huerta de Soto (2012 [1998]).

  2. 2

    Huerta de Soto (2012 [1998], chapter 9).

  3. 3

    Hayek (1971 [1937]).

  4. 4

    Though Hayek does not expressly name them, he is referring to the theorists of the Chicago school, led by Milton Friedman, who in this and other areas shake hands with the Keynesians.

  5. 5

    Later we will see how, with a single currency like the euro, the disciplinary role of fixed exchange rates is taken on by the current market value of each country’s sovereign and corporate debt.

  6. 6

    To underline Mises’s argument even more clearly, I should indicate that there is no way to justifiably attribute to the gold standard the error Churchill committed following World War I, when he fixed the gold parity without taking into account the serious inflation of pound sterling banknotes issued to finance the war. This event has nothing to do with the current situation of the euro, which is freely floating in international markets, nor with those problems which affect countries in the euro zone’s periphery and which stem from the loss in real competitiveness suffered by their economies during the bubble (Huerta de Soto 2012 [1998], 447, 622–3 in the English edition).

  7. 7

    At least in Spain, two MPS meetings and decades clamoring by free market economists for the introduction of these (and many other) reforms have been almost useless and unable to stop the growth of the state and only now have become politically feasible, and have done so suddenly, with surprising urgency, and due to the euro. Two observations: first, the measures which constitute a step in the right direction have been sullied by the increase in taxes, especially on income, movable capital earnings, wealth and value added tax, which as expected have failed to increase significantly public revenues (see the manifesto against the tax increase which I and 50 other academics signed in February 2012 – www.juandemariana.org/nota/5371/manifiesto/subida/impositiva/respeto/senor); second, the principles of budget stability and equilibrium are a necessary, but not a sufficient, condition for a return to the path toward a sustainable economy, since in the event of another episode of credit expansion, only a huge surplus during the prosperous years would make it possible, once the inevitable recession hit, to avoid the grave problems that now affect us.

  8. 8

    For the first time, and thanks to the euro, Greece is facing up to the challenges its own future poses. Though blasé monetarists and recalcitrant Keynesians do not wish to recognize it, internal deflation is possible and does not involve any “perverse” cycle if accompanied by major reforms to liberalize the economy and regain competitiveness. It is true that Greece has received and is receiving substantial aid, but it is no less true that it has the historic responsibility to refute the predictions of all those prophets of doom who, for different reasons, are determined to see the failure of the Greek effort so they can retain in their models the very stale (and self-interested) hypothesis that prices (and wages) are downwardly rigid (see also our remarks in footnote 9 about the disastrous effects of Argentina’s highly praised devaluation of 2001). For the first time, the traditionally bankrupt and corrupt Greek state has taken a drastic remedy. In two years (2010–2011) the public deficit has dropped 8 % points; the salaries of public servants have been cut by 15% initially and another 20% after that, and their number has been reduced by over 80,000 employees and the number of town councils by almost half; the retirement age has been raised; the minimum wage has been lowered, etc. (Vidal-Folch 2012). This “heroic” reconstruction contrasts with the economic and social decomposition of Argentina, which took the opposite (Keynesian and monetarist) road of monetary nationalism, devaluation, and inflation.

  9. 9

    Therefore, fortunately, we are “chained to the euro,” to use Cabrillo’s apt expression (Cabrillo 2012). Perhaps the most hackneyed contemporary example Keynesians and monetarists offer to illustrate the “merits” of a devaluation and of the abandonment of a fixed rate is the case of Argentina following the bank freeze (“corralito”) that took place beginning in December of 2001. This example is seriously erroneous for two reasons. First, at most, the bank freeze is simply an illustration of the fact that a fractional-reserve banking system cannot possibly function without a lender of last resort (Huerta de Soto 2012 [1998], 785–6). Second, following the highly praised devaluation, Argentina’s per capita GDP fell from 7,726 dollars in 2000 to 2,767 dollars in 2002, thus losing two-thirds of its value. This 65% drop in Argentinian income and wealth should give serious pause to all those who nowadays are clumsily and violently demonstrating, for example in Greece, to protest the relatively much smaller sacrifices and drops in prices involved in the healthy and inevitable internal deflation which the discipline of the euro is requiring. Furthermore, all the patter about Argentina’s “impressive” growth rates, of over 8% per year beginning in 2003, should impress us very little if at all, when we consider the very low starting point after the devaluation, as well as the poverty, paralysis, and chaotic nature of the Argentinian economy, where one-third of the population has ended up depending on subsidies and government aid, the real rate of inflation exceeds 30%, and scarcity, restrictions, regulations, demagogy, the lack of reforms, and government control (and recklessness) have become a matter of course (Gallo 2012). Along the same lines, Pierpaolo Barbieri states: “I find truly incredible that serious commentators like economist Nouriel Roubini are offering Argentina as a role model for Greece” (Barbieri 2012).

  10. 10

    Even the President of the ECB, Mario Draghi, has gone so far as to expressly state that the “continent’s social model is ‘gone’” (Blackstone et al. 2012).

  11. 11

    Only in this way all the malinvestment financed during the previous credit bubble can be quickly “digested” and liquidated.

  12. 12

    I do not include here the analysis of my esteemed disciple and colleague Philipp Bagus (2010), since from Germany’s point of view, the manipulation to which the European Central Bank is subjecting the euro threatens the monetary stability Germany traditionally enjoyed with the mark. Nevertheless, his argument that the euro has fostered irresponsible policies via a typical tragedy-of-the-commons effect seems weaker to me, because during the bubble stage, most of the countries that are now having problems, with the only possible exception of Greece, were showing a surplus in their public accounts (or were very close to one). Thus, I believe Bagus would have been more accurate if he had titled his otherwise excellent book “The Tragedy of the European Central Bank” (and not of the euro), particularly in light of the grave errors committed by the European Central Bank during the bubble stage, errors we will remark on in a later section of this article (thanks to Juan Ramón Rallo for suggesting this idea to me).

  13. 13

    The editorial line of the defunct Spanish newspaper Público was paradigmatic in this sense. (See also, for example, the case of Estefanía [2011], and of his criticism of the aforementioned reform of article 135 of the Spanish Constitution to establish the “anti-Keynesian” principle of budget stability and equilibrium.)

  14. 14

    See, for example, the statements of the socialist candidate for the French presidency, for whom “the path of austerity is ineffective, deadly, and dangerous” (Hollande 2012), or those of the far-right candidate, Marine Le Pen, who believes the French “should return to the franc and bring the euro period to a close once and for all” (Martín Ferrand 2012).

  15. 15

    One example among many articles is Krugman (2012a); see also Stiglitz (2012).

  16. 16

    The US public deficit has stood at between 8.2% and 10% over the last three years, in sharp contrast with German deficit, which stood at only 1% in 2011.

  17. 17

    An up-to-date explanation of the Austrian theory of the cycle can be found in Huerta de Soto (2012 [1998], chapter 5).

  18. 18
  19. 19

    A legion of economists belong to this group, and most of them (surprise, surprise!) come from the dollar-pound area. Among others in the group, I could mention, for example, Robert Barro (2012), Martin Feldstein (2011), and President Barack Obama’s adviser, Austan Goolsbee (2011). In Spain, though for different reasons, I should cite such eminent economists as Pedro Schwartz, Francisco Cabrillo, and Alberto Recarte.

  20. 20

    See how Krugman quotes Friedman to support his position in his last book (Krugman 2012b, chapter 10).

  21. 21

    Mundell (1961). Paradoxically although Mundell proposed and defended the introduction of the Euro since 1969 he provided in his seminal essay on the optimum currency areas the theoretical ammunition used by his detractors.

  22. 22
  23. 23

    See Whyte’s (2011) excellent analysis of the serious harm the depreciation of the pound is causing in United Kingdom; and with respect to the United States, see Laperriere (2012).

  24. 24
  25. 25

    “The euro, as the currency of an economic zone that exports more than the United States, has well-developed financial markets, and is supported by a world class central bank, is in many aspects the obvious alternative to the dollar. While currently it is fashionable to couch all discussions of the euro in doom and gloom, the fact is that the euro accounts for 37% of all foreign exchange market turnover. It accounts for 31% of all international bond issues. It represents 28% of the foreign exchange reserves whose currency composition is divulged by central banks” (Eichengreen 2011, 130). Guy Sorman, for his part, has commented on “the ambiguous attitude of US financial experts and actors. They have never liked the euro, because by definition, the euro competes with the dollar: following orders, American so-called experts explained to us that the euro could not survive without a central economic government and a single fiscal system” (Sorman 2011). In short, it is clear that champions of competition between currencies should direct their efforts against the monopoly of the dollar (for example, by supporting the euro), rather than advocate the reintroduction of, and competition between, “little local currencies” of minor importance (the drachma, escudo, peseta, lira, pound, franc, and even the mark).

  26. 26

    Such is the case with, for example, the contest held in the United Kingdom by Lord Wolfson, the owner of Next stores. Up to now, this contest has attracted no fewer than 650 “experts” and crackpots. Were it not for the crass and obvious hypocrisy involved in such initiatives, which are always held outside the euro area (and especially in the Anglo-Saxon world, by those who fear, hate, or scorn the euro), we should commend the great effort and interest shown in the fate of a currency which, after all, is not their own.

  27. 27

    It might be worth noting that the author of these lines is a “Eurosceptic” who maintains that the function of the European Union should be limited exclusively to guaranteeing the free circulation of people, capital, and goods in the context of a single currency (if possible the gold standard).

  28. 28

    I have already mentioned, for instance, the recent legislative changes that have delayed the retirement age to 67 (and even indexed it with respect to future trends in life expectancy), changes already introduced or on the way in Germany, France, Italy, Spain, Portugal, and Greece. I could also cite the establishment of a “copayment” and increasing areas of privatization in connection with health care. These are small steps in the right direction, which, because of their high political cost, would not have been taken without the euro. They also contrast with the opposite trend indicated by Barack Obama’s health-care reform, and with the obvious resistance to change when it comes to tackling the inevitable reform of the British National Health Service.

  29. 29
  30. 30
  31. 31

    See, for example, “United States’ Economy: Over-regulated America: The home of laissez-faire is being suffocated by excessive and badly written regulation,” The Economist, February 18, 2012, p. 8, and the examples there cited.

  32. 32
  33. 33

    On the hysterical support for the grandiose fiscal stimulus packages of this period, see Fernando Ulrich (2011).

  34. 34
  35. 35

    Specifically, the average rise in M3 in the euro zone from 2000 to 2011 exceeded 6.3%, and we should highlight the increases that occurred during the bubble years 2005 (from 7% to 8%), 2006 (from 8% to 10%), and 2007 (from 10% to 12%). The above data show that, as has already been indicated, the goal of a zero deficit, though commendable, is merely a necessary, though not a sufficient, condition for stability: during the expansionary phase of a cycle induced by credit expansion, public-spending commitments may be made based on the false tranquility which surpluses generate, yet later, when the inevitable recession hits, these commitments are completely unsustainable. This demonstrates that the objective of a zero deficit also requires an economy that is not subject to the ups and downs of credit expansion, or at least that the budgets be closed out with much larger surpluses during the expansionary years. See also Balcerowicz (2010).

  36. 36

    Therefore, Greece would be the only case to which we could apply the “tragedy of the commons” argument Bagus (2010) develops concerning the euro. In light of the reasoning I have presented in the text, and as I have already mentioned, I believe a more apt title for Bagus’s remarkable book, The Tragedy of the Euro, would have been The Tragedy of the European Central Bank.

  37. 37

    The surpluses in Spain were as follows: 0.96%, 2.02%, and 1.90% in 2005, 2006, and 2007 respectively. Those of Ireland were: 0.42%, 1.40%, 1.64%, 2.90%, and 0.67% in 2003, 2004, 2005, 2006, and 2007 respectively.

  38. 38

    The author of these lines could be cited as an exception (Huerta de Soto 2012 [1998], xxxvii).

  39. 39

    Ibid.

  40. 40

    In fiscal year 2011 Federal Reserve directly bought 77% of the newly issued American public debt (Gramm and Taylor 2012). A similar statement can be made regarding the Bank of England, which is the direct holder of 25% of all the sovereign public debt of the United Kingdom. In comparison with these figures, the (direct and indirect) monetization carried out by the European Central Bank seems like innocent “child’s play.”

  41. 41

    Luskin and Roche Kelly have even referred to “Europe’s Supply-Side Revolution” (Luskin and Roche Kelly 2012). Also highly significant is “A Plan for Growth in Europe,” which was urged February 20, 2012 by the leaders of 12 countries in the European Union (including Italy, Spain, the Netherlands, Finland, Ireland, and Poland), a plan which comprises only supply-side policies and does not mention any fiscal stimulus measure. There is also the manifesto “Initiative for a Free and Prospering Europe” (IFPE) signed in Bratislava in January 2012 by, among others, the author of these lines. In short, a change of models seems a priority in countries which, like Spain, must move from a speculative, “hot” economy based on credit expansion to a “cold” economy based on competitiveness. Indeed, as soon as prices decline (“internal deflation”) and the structure of relative prices is readjusted in an environment of economic liberalization and structural reforms, numerous opportunities for entrepreneurial profit will arise in sustainable investments, which in a monetary area as extensive as the euro area are sure to attract financing. This is how to bring about the necessary rehabilitation and ensure the longed-for recovery in our economies, a recovery which again should be cold, sustainable, and based on competitiveness.

  42. 42

    In this context, and as I explained in the section devoted to the “Motley Anti-euro Coalition,” we should not be surprised by the statements of the candidates to the French presidency, which are mentioned in footnote 14.

  43. 43

    Estimated data as of December 31, 2011.

  44. 44

    Elsewhere I have mentioned the incremental reforms which, like the radical separation between commercial and investment banking (as in the Glass Steagall Act), could improve the euro somewhat. At the same time, it is in United Kingdom where, paradoxically (or not, in light of the devastating social damage that has resulted from its banking crisis), my proposals have aroused the most interest, to the point that a bill was even presented in the British Parliament to complete Peel’s Bank Charter Act of 1844 (curiously, still in effect) by extending the 100% reserve requirement to demand deposits (Hansard, vol. 515, no. 46, pp. 904–05). The consensus reached there to separate commercial and investment banking should be considered a (very small) step in the right direction (Huerta de Soto 2010, 2011).

  45. 45

    My uncle by marriage, the entrepreneur Javier Vidal Sario from Navarre, who remains perfectly lucid and active at the age of 94, assures me that in all his life, he had never, not even during the years of the Stabilization Plan of 1959, witnessed in Spain a collective effort at institutional and budget discipline and economic rehabilitation comparable to the current one. Also historically significant is the fact that this effort is not taking place in just one country (for example, Spain), nor in relation to one local currency (for example, the old peseta), but rather is spread throughout all of Europe, and is being made by hundreds of millions of people in the framework of a common monetary unit (the euro).

  46. 46

    As early as 1924, the great American economist Benjamin M. Anderson wrote the following: “Economical living, prudent financial policy, debt reduction rather than debt creation – all these things are imperative if Europe is to be restored. And all these are consistent with a greatly improved standard of living in Europe, if real activity be set going once more. The gold standard, together with natural discount and interest rates, can supply the most solid possible foundation for such a course of events in Europe.” Clearly, once again, history is repeating itself (Anderson 1924). I am grateful to my colleague Antonio Zanella for having called my attention to this excerpt.

  47. 47

    Moreover, this historic situation is now being revisited in all its severity upon China, the economy of which is at this time on the brink of expansionary and inflationary collapse. See “Keynes versus Hayek in China,” The Economist, December 30, 2011, as well as “Free exchange: Hayek on the standing committee”, The Economist, September 15, 2012, p. 64.

  48. 48

    As we have already seen, Mises, the great defender of the gold standard and 100%-reserve free banking, in the 1960s collided head-on with theorists who, led by Friedman, supported flexible exchange rates. Mises decried the behavior of his disciple Machlup, when the latter abandoned the defense of fixed exchange rates. Now, 50 years later and on account of the euro, history is also repeating itself. On that occasion, the advocates of monetary nationalism and exchange-rate instability won, with consequences we are all familiar with. This time around let us hope that the lesson has been learned and that Mises’s views will prevail. The world needs it and he deserves it.

Published Online: 2013-12-3

©2013 by Walter de Gruyter Berlin / Boston

Downloaded on 7.5.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/jeeh-2013-0012/html
Scroll to top button