Skip to main content
Log in

On the coalitional stability of monopoly power in differentiated Bertrand and Cournot oligopolies

  • Published:
Theory and Decision Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this article, we revisit the classic comparison between Bertrand and Cournot competition in the presence of a cartel of firms that faces outsiders acting individually. This competition setting enables to deal with both non-cooperative and cooperative oligopoly games. We concentrate on industries consisting of symmetrically differentiated products where firms operate at a constant and identical marginal cost. First, while the standard Bertrand–Cournot rankings still hold for Nash equilibrium prices, we show that the results may be altered for Nash equilibrium quantities and profits. Second, we define cooperative Bertrand and Cournot oligopoly games with transferable utility on the basis of their non-cooperative foundation. We establish that the core of a cooperative Cournot oligopoly game is strictly included in the core of a cooperative Bertrand oligopoly game when the number of firms is lower or equal to 25. Moreover, we focus on the aggregate-monotonic core, a subset of the core, that has the advantage to select point solutions satisfying both core selection and aggregate monotonicity properties. We succeed in comparing the aggregate-monotonic cores between Bertrand and Cournot competition regardless of the number of firms. Finally, we study a class of three-firm oligopolies with asymmetric costs in which the core inclusion property mentioned above still holds. We also provide numerical examples to illustrate the difficulty to generalize this result to an arbitrary number of firms because of negative equilibrium quantities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. An example of a cartel with formal collusion is California’s Raisin Administrative Committee created in 1949 as a result of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937.

  2. The condition \(V>c\) ensures that equilibrium quantities and prices will be positive.

  3. The case of complementary products (\(r<0\)) is not considered in the current model.

  4. Equivalently, this consists in finding a quasi-hybrid solution of a multiple objective game (Zhao 1991). A Nash equilibrium involving a subset of players correlating their strategies is also called a partial agreement equilibrium by Chander and Tulkens (1997).

  5. This uniqueness result is proved in Sect. 3.

  6. The expressions of Nash equilibrium quantities produced by each cartel member and each outsider in Bertrand and Cournot competition are given by (17), (18), (20), and (21) in the appendix.

  7. Rational number k can be interpreted as the weight of the cartel in the industry. For example, \(k=2\) means that the cartel represents half of the total number of firms in the industry. This permits to study asymptotically when \(n\rightarrow \infty \) the behaviors of cartel members and outsiders.

  8. The expressions of Nash equilibrium profits of each cartel member in Bertrand and Cournot competition are given by (19) and (22) in the appendix.

  9. This condition ensures that equilibrium quantities are positive.

  10. The expressions of asymptotic reaction functions are given in Sect. 6.3 in the appendix. Furthermore, it is proved that both the y-intercepts and the absolute value of the slopes of asymptotic reaction function \(\bar{R}_I^B(q_j)\) are higher than those of reaction function \(R_I^C(q_j)\).

  11. The matlab program we used in this proof is available to readers upon request. In a lexicographical order on (ns), the first two positive roots \(r_1\simeq 14.91\) and \(r_2\simeq 22.26\) appear when \(n=26\) and \(s=11\). This implies that \(p(r)<0\) for any \(r\in ]r_1,r_2[\).

  12. This difference is negative for \(n\in \lbrace {3,4}\rbrace \) and r sufficiently large. This is in line with Salant et al. (1983) who have observed that horizontal mergers may be disadvantageous to member firms.

  13. On the set of balanced TU-games, the core of a root game \((N,v_R)\) coincides with the contraction core introduced by Gonzalez and Lardon (2018). For any symmetric TU-game, Gonzalez and Lardon (2018) have proved that the contraction core is a singleton.

References

  • Amir, R., & Jin, J. Y. (2001). Cournot and Bertrand equilibria compared: substitutability, complementarity and concavity. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 19, 303–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann, R.J. (1959). Acceptable points in general cooperative n-person games. In: A. Tucker, & R. Luce (eds.), Contributions to the theory of games IV. Princeton: Princeton University Press. https://doi.org/10.1515/9781400882168-018.

  • Bloch, F. (1995). Endogenous structures of association in oligopolies. RAND Journal of Economics, 26(3), 537–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bondareva, O. N. (1963). Some applications of linear programming methods to the theory of cooperative games. Problemi Kibernetiki, 10, 119–139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calleja, P., Rafels, C., & Tijs, S. (2009). The Aggregate–Monotonic core. Games and Economic Behavior, 66(2), 742–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chander, P., & Tulkens, H. (1997). The core of an economy with multilateral environmental externalities. International Journal of Game Theory, 26, 379–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, L. (1985). Comparing Bertrand and Cournot equilibria: A geometric approach. Rand Journal of Economics, 16(1), 146–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Currarini, S., & Marini, M. (2003). A sequential approach to the characteristic function and the core in games with externalities. In: M. R. Sertel, & S. Koray (Eds.), Advances in economic design. Studies in economic design. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer.

  • Currarini, S., & Marini, M. (2015). Coalitional approaches to collusive agreements in oligopoly games. Manchester School, 83(3), 253–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dastidar, K. G. (1997). Comparing Cournot and Bertrand in a Homogeneous Product Market. Journal of Economic Theory, 75, 205–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deneckere, R., & Davidson, C. (1985). Incentives to form coalitions with Bertrand competition. The RAND Journal of economics, 16, 473–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donsimoni, M. P. (1985). Stable heterogeneous cartels. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 3, 451–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, J. W. (1971). A non-cooperative equilibrium for supergames. Review of Economic Studies, 38, 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabszewicz, J. J., Marini, M. A., & Tarola, O. (2016). Core existence in vertically differentiated markets. Economics Letters, 149, 28–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, S., & Lardon, A. (2018). Optimal deterrence of cooperation. International Journal of Game Theory, 47, 207–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Häckner, J. (2000). A note on price and quantity competition in differentiated oligopolies. Journal of Economic Theory, 93, 233–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, S., & Kurz, M. (1983). Endogeneous formation of coalitions. Econometrica, 51(4), 1047–1064.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huck, S., Konrad, K. A., & Müller, W. (2005). Profitable horizontal mergers without cost advantages: The role of internal organization, information and market structure. Economica, 71(284), 575–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konishi, H., & Lin, P. (1999). Stable cartels with a Cournot fringe in a symmetric oligopoly. Keio Economic Studies, 36, 1–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lardon, A. (2012). The \(\gamma \)-core of Cournot oligopoly games with capacity constraints. Theory and Decision, 72(3), 387–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lardon, A. (2019). Convexity of Bertrand oligopoly TU-games with differentiated products. Annals of Operations Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-019-03351-7.

  • Lekeas, P. V., & Stamatopoulos, G. (2014). Cooperative oligopoly games with boundedly rational firms. Annals of Operations Research, 223(1), 255–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lofaro, A. (2002). On the efficiency of Bertrand and Cournot competition under incomplete information. European Journal of Political Economy, 18, 561–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meggido, N. (1974). On the nonmonotonicity of the bargaining set, the kernel and the nucleolus of a game. SIAM Journal on Applied Mathematics, 27, 355–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N. H., & Pazgal, A. I. (2001). The equivalence of price and quantity competition with delegation. RAND Journal of Economics, 32(2), 284–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nash, J. F. (1950). The bargaining problem. Econometrica, 18, 155–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norde, H., Pham Do, K. H., & Tijs, S. (2002). Oligopoly games with and without transferable technologies. Mathematical Social Sciences, 43, 187–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okuguchi, K. (1987). Equilibrium prices in the Bertrand and Cournot oligopolies. Journal of Economic Theory, 42, 128–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pal, R. (2015). Cournot vs. Bertrand under relative performance delegation: Implications of positive and negative networks externalities. Mathematical Social Sciences, 75, 94–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R. (1989). Endogenous coalition formation in cooperative oligopolies. International Economic Review, 30(4), 863–876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ray, D., & Vohra, R. (1997). Equilibrium binding agreements. Journal of Economic Theory, 73(1), 30–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salant, S., Switzer, S., & Reynolds, R. J. (1983). Losses from horizontal merger: The effects of an exogeneous change in industry structure on Cournot–Nash equilibrium. Quaterly Journal of Economics XCVII, I(2), 185–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer, S. (1995). Stable cartels with a Cournot fringe. Southern Economic Journal, 61(3), 744–754.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley, L. S. (1955). Markets as cooperative games (p. 629). Santa Monica, Calif: RAND Corporation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapley, L. S. (1967). On balanced sets and cores. Naval Research Logistics Quaterly, 14, 453–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shubik, M. (1980). Market structure and behavior. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, N., & Vives, X. (1984). Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. RAND Journal of Economics, 15(4), 546–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takeda, K., Hosoe, T., Watanabe, T., & Matsubayashi, N. (2018). Stability analysis of horizontal mergers in a market with asymmetric substitutability. Mathematical Social Sciences, 96, 73–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thrall, R., & Lucas, W. (1963). \(N\)-person games in partition function form. Naval Research Logistics Quaterly, 10, 281–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vasconcelos, H. (2006). Endogenous mergers in endogenous sunk cost industries. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24(2), 227–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vives, X. (1985). On the efficiency of Bertrand and Cournot equilibria with product differentiation. Journal of Economic Theory, 36, 166–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, X. H., & Zhao, J. (2007). Welfare reductions from small cost reductions in differentiated oligopoly. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 25, 173–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, X. H., & Zhao, J. (2010). Why are firms sometimes unwilling to reduce costs? Journal of Economics, 101(2), 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe, T., & Matsubayashi, N. (2013). Note on stable mergers in a market with asymmetric substitutability. Economics Bulletin, 33(3), 2024–2033.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yi, S. S. (1997). Stable coalition structures with externalities. Games and Economic Behavior, 20(2), 201–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, J. (1991). The equilibria of a multiple objective game. International Journal of Game Theory, 20, 171–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, J. (1999). A \(\beta \)-core existence result and its application to oligopoly markets. Games and Economic Behavior, 27, 153–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, J. (2001). The relative interior of the base polyhedron and the core. Economic Theory, 18, 635–648.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zu, L., Zhang, J., & Wang, S. (2012). The size of stable cartels: An analytical approach. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 30(2), 217–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aymeric Lardon.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

I would like to thank Francis Bloch for suggesting me the idea to compare the cores between Bertrand and Cournot competition. I also wish to thank Philippe Solal for providing numerous suggestions that substantially improved the exposition of the article.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Geometrical properties of the reaction functions in price space

  • Comparison of the y-intercepts of \(R_I^B(p_j)\) and \(\bar{R}_I^C(p_j)\) given by (9) and (13), respectively:

    $$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{(n+rs)nV}{2n^2(1+r)+nr^2s-r^2s^2}-\frac{nV}{2(n+r(n-s))}&=\frac{nVr^2s(n-s)}{2(n+r(n-s))(2n^2(1+r)+nr^2s-r^2s^2)}\\&>0\text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
  • Comparison of the slopes of \(R_I^B(p_j)\) and \(\bar{R}_I^C(p_j)\) given by (9) and (13), respectively:

    $$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{(n+rs)r(n-s)}{2n^2(1+r)+nr^2s-r^2s^2}-\frac{r(n-s)}{2(n+r(n-s))}&=\frac{r^3(n-s)^2s}{2(n+r(n-s))(2n^2(1+r)+nr^2s-r^2s^2)}\\&>0\text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
  • Comparison of the y-intercepts of \(R_O^B(p_i)\) and \(\bar{R}_O^C(p_i)\) given by (10) and (14), respectively:

    $$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{(n+r)nV}{n^2(2+r)+nr(s+1)+r^2s}&-\frac{nV}{2n+r(n+s-1)} \\&=\frac{nV(n-1)r^2}{(2n+r(n+s-1))(n^2(2+r)+nr(s+1)+r^2s)} >0\text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
  • Comparison of the slopes of \(R_O^B(p_i)\) and \(\bar{R}_O^C(p_i)\) given by (10) and (14), respectively:

    $$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{(n+r)rs}{n^2(2+r)+nr(s+1)+r^2s}&-\frac{rs}{2n+r(n+s-1)} \\&=\frac{r^3(n-1)s}{(2n+r(n+s-1))(n^2(2+r)+nr(s+1)+r^2s)} >0\text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

1.2 Geometrical properties of the reaction functions in quantity space

  • Comparison of the y-intercepts of \(R_I^C(q_j)\) and \(\bar{R}_I^B(q_j)\) given by (11) and (15), respectively:

    $$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{(n+r(n-s))(1+r)nV}{2n^2(1+r)+nr^2s-r^2s^2}-\frac{(1+r)nV}{2(n+rs)}&=\frac{nVr^2(1+r)(n-s)s}{2(n+rs)(2n^2(1+r)+nr^2s-r^2s^2)}\\&>0\text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
  • Comparison of the absolute value of the slopes of \(R_I^C(q_j)\) and \(\bar{R}_I^B(q_j)\) given by (11) and (15), respectively:

    $$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{(n+r(n-s))r(n-s)}{2n^2(1+r)+nr^2s-r^2s^2}-\frac{r(n-s)}{2(n+rs)}&=\frac{r^3(n-s)^2s}{2(n+rs)(2n^2(1+r)+nr^2s-r^2s^2)}\\&>0\text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
  • Comparison of the y-intercepts of \(R_O^C(q_i)\) and \(\bar{R}_O^B(q_i)\) given by (12) and (16), respectively:

    $$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&\frac{(n(1+r)-r)(1+r)nV}{n^2(2+3r+r^2)-nr(1+r)(s+1)+r^2s} -\frac{nV(1+r)}{2n+r(n-s+1)} \\&\quad =\frac{nV(n-1)r^2(1+r)}{(2n+r(n-s+1))(n^2(2+3r+r^2)+nr(-rs-s-r-1)+r^2s)} >0\text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
  • Comparison of the absolute value of the slopes of \(R_O^C(q_i)\) and \(\bar{R}_O^B(q_i)\) given by (12) and (16), respectively:

    $$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&\frac{(n(1+r)-r)rs}{n^2(2+3r+r^2)-nr(1+r)(s+1)+r^2s} -\frac{rs}{2n+r(n-s+1)} \\&\quad =\frac{r^3(n-1)s}{(2n+r(n-s+1))(n^2(2+3r+r^2)+nr(-rs-s-r-1)+r^2s)} >0\text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

1.3 The asymptotic reaction functions in quantity space

By substituting s by n / k into (11), (12), (15), and (16), and taking the limit \(n\rightarrow \infty \), the cartel asymptotic reaction functions are expressed as:

$$\begin{aligned} R_I^C(q_j)=\frac{(1+r)kV-r(k-1)q_j}{2(k+r)}\text{, } \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}_I^B(q_j)=\frac{(r(k-1)+k)((1+r)kV-r(k-1)q_j)}{(k-1)r^2+2k^2r+2k^2}\text{. } \end{aligned}$$

The asymptotic reaction functions of any outsider are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} R_O^C(q_i)=\bar{R}_O^B(q_i)=\frac{(1+r)kV-rq_i}{2k+(k-1)r}\text{. } \end{aligned}$$
  • Comparison of the y-intercepts of \(R_I^C(q_j)\) and \(\bar{R}_I^B(q_j)\) in the asymptotic case:

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{(r(k-1)+k)(1+r)kV}{(k-1)r^2+2k^2r+2k^2}-\frac{(1+r)kV}{2(k+r)} =\frac{(k-1)kr^2(1+r)V}{2(k+r)((k-1)r^2+2k^2r+2k^2)} >0\text{. } \end{aligned}$$
  • Comparison of the absolute value of the slopes of \(R_I^C(q_j)\) and \(\bar{R}_I^B(q_j)\) in the asymptotic case:

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{(r(k-1)+k)(k-1)r}{(k-1)r^2+2k^2r+2k^2}-\frac{r(k-1)}{2(k+r)}=\frac{(k-1)^2r^3}{2(k+r)((k-1)r^2+2k^2r+2k^2)} >0\text{. } \end{aligned}$$

1.4 Proofs

In this subsection, the expressions (17)–(22) are all available in Wang and Zhao (2010) by letting all marginal costs be zero.

Proof of Proposition 3.2:

In quantity space, the intersections of reaction functions \(R_I^C(q_j)\) and \(R_O^C(q_i)\), and \(\bar{R}_I^B(q_j)\) and \(\bar{R}_O^B(q_i)\) given by (11), (12), (15) and (16), respectively, provide Nash equilibrium quantities produced by each cartel member in Bertrand and Cournot competition, respectively:

$$\begin{aligned} D_i(p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s) =\frac{V(2n(1+r)-r)(r(n-s)+n)}{4n^2+r(n(6n-2(s+1)) +r(n-s)(2n+s-2))} \end{aligned}$$
(17)

and

$$\begin{aligned} q_s^* =\frac{nV(2n+r)(1+r)}{4n^2+2rn(1+n)+rs((n+2)r+2n)-r^2s^2}\text{. } \end{aligned}$$

Calculating the difference between these two quantities leads to:

$$\begin{aligned} D_i(p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_j)-q_s^* =\frac{Vr^2(n-s)p(r)}{AB}\text{, } \end{aligned}$$

where \(A>0\) and \(B>0\) denote the denominators of \(D_i(p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s)\) and \(q_s^*\) respectively, and p(r) is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} p(r) =&r^2(2n((n-s)(s-1)+1)+s(s-2))\\&+\,r2n(s(2n-s)+n(s-1)+1)\\&+\,4n^2s\\&>0, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

which concludes the proof. \(\square \)

Fig. 4
figure 4

Asymptotic Nash equilibrium quantities

A similar argument to the one in the proof of Proposition 3.2 permits to determine Nash equilibrium quantities produced by each outsider in Bertrand competition:

$$\begin{aligned} D_j(p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s)=\frac{V(2n(1+r)-rs)(r(n-1)+n)}{4n^2+r(n(6n-2(s+1))+r(n-s)(2n+s-2))}. \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Proof of Proposition 3.3:

Consider the asymptotic case of an industry containing an infinite number of firms \(n\rightarrow \infty \) with a cartel of significant size \(s\rightarrow \infty /k=\infty \) as illustrated in Fig. 4. As a consequence, the asymptotic reaction functions of any cartel member \(\bar{R}_I^B(q_j)\) and \(R_I^C(q_j)\) differ for any \(k>1\).Footnote 10 By contrast, since each outsider acts as a price-taking profit maximizer, its asymptotic reaction functions \(\bar{R}_O^B(q_i)\) and \(R_O^C(q_i)\) are equal (see footnote 10). In quantity space, decompose the quantity change from B to C into two stages. First, it follows from Proposition 3.2 that each cartel member reduces its quantity from \(D_i(p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s)\) to \(q_s^*\) to achieve A which raises price for all outsiders. Second, in response, each atomic outsider must increase its own quantity from \(D_j(p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s)\) to \({\tilde{q}}_s\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3.4:

In quantity space, decompose the quantity change from B to C into two stages as illustrated in Figs. 2 and 3. First, each cartel member reduces its quantity from \(D_i(p_s^*,p_j^*)\) to \(q_s^*\) to achieve A. By gross substitutability, this raises price for all outsiders, and hence benefits them. Second, facing \(q_s^*\), each outsider reduces its quantity (Fig. 2) or raises it (Fig. 3) to \({\tilde{q}}_s\) to achieve C which is profit-maximizing.

When each outsider reduces its quantity from Bertrand to Cournot competition, a similar argument permits to conclude that each cartel member earns larger profits by decomposing the quantity change from B to C via D (Fig. 2). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3.5:

In price space, the intersection of reaction functions \(R_I^B(p_j)\) and \(R_O^B(p_i)\) given by (9) and (10), respectively, provides Nash equilibrium prices charged by each cartel member:

$$\begin{aligned} p_s^*=\frac{\displaystyle V\big (2n(1+r)-r\big )n}{\displaystyle 2\big (2n+r(n+s-1)\big )\big (n+r(n-s)\big )-r^2s(n-s)}\text{, } \end{aligned}$$

and by each outsider:

$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{p}}_s=\frac{\displaystyle V\big (2n(1+r)-r s\big )n}{\displaystyle 2\big (2n+r(n+s-1)\big )\big (n+r(n-s)\big )-r^2s(n-s)}\text{. } \end{aligned}$$

The profit of each cartel member at Bertrand–Nash equilibrium \((p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s)\) is expressed as:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^B(p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s)=\frac{V^2(2n(1+r)-r)^2n(n+r(n-s))}{\big (4n^2+6n^2r-2nrs +2n^2r^2-r^2s^2-2nr-2nr^2+2r^2s-nr^2s\big )^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(19)

In quantity space, the intersection of reaction functions \(R_I^C(q_j)\) and \(R_O^C(q_i)\) given by (11) and (12), respectively, provides Nash equilibrium quantities produced by each cartel member:

$$\begin{aligned} q_s^*=\frac{\displaystyle V(2n+r)(1+r)n}{\displaystyle 4n^2+2rn(1+n)+rs((n+2)r+2n)-r^2s^2} \end{aligned}$$
(20)

and by each outsider:

$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{q}}_s=\frac{\displaystyle V(2n+rs)(1+r)n}{\displaystyle 4n^2+2rn(1+n)+rs((n+2)r+2n)-r^2s^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(21)

The profit of each cartel member at Cournot–Nash equilibrium \((q_s^*,{\tilde{q}}_s)\) is expressed as:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^C(q_s^*,{\tilde{q}}_s)=\frac{V^2((2n+r)^2n(n+rs)(1+r))}{(4n^2+2rn(1+n)+rs((n+2)r+2n)-r^2s^2)^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Calculating the difference between the profits given by (19) and (22) leads to:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^C(q_s^*,{\tilde{q}}_s)-\pi _i^B(p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s) =\frac{\displaystyle nr^3(2+r)(n-s)V^2p(r)}{\displaystyle A^2B^2}\text{, } \end{aligned}$$

where \(A^2\) and \(B^2\) denote the denominators of \(\pi _i^C(q_s^*,{\tilde{q}}_s)\) and \(\pi _i^B(p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s)\) respectively, and p(r) is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}p(r) =&r^4(s(n-s)(2n+s-2)^2) \\&+\,r^34n^2(n^2(-s^2+4s+1)+n(2s^3-3s^2-3s-2)-s^4-s^3+4s^2-s+1)\\&+\,r^24n^2(4n^3+n^2(-s^2+4s-3)+n(2s^3-3s^2-3s-2)-s^4-s^3+4s^2-s+1)\\&+\,r(32n^5-32n^4)+\,16n^5-16n^4{.} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

It remains to study p(r). Note that for any n and any \(s< n\), it holds that \(p(r)>0\) when r is sufficiently small or sufficiently large. Two cases can occur:

  • for any \(r>0\), \(p(r)>0\), i.e., p(r) has no positive root.

  • there exists a root \(r_1>0\) which implies that \(p(r)<0\) at the neighborhood of \(r_1\).

A simple algorithm permitting to compute roots of p(r) shows that no positive root appears for any \(n\le 25\) and any \(s< n\).Footnote 11\(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3.6:

By substituting s by n / k into (19) and (22), the difference between these two profits becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^C(q_s^*,{\tilde{q}}_s)-\pi _i^B(p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s)=\frac{\displaystyle (k-1)k^3r^3(r+2)V^2p(n)}{\displaystyle A^2B^2}\text{, } \end{aligned}$$

where \((An/k^2)^2\) and \((Bn/k^2)^2\) denote the denominators of \(\pi _i^C(q_s^*,{\tilde{q}}_s)\), and \(\pi _i^B (p_s^*,{\tilde{p}}_s)\), respectively, and p(n) is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}p(n) =&-n^4(4(r^3+r^2)(k^2-2k+1)) \\&+n^3k(r^3(16k^2-12k-4)+r^2(16k^3+16k^2-12k-4)+16k^3(2r+1))\\&+n^2(r^4(4k^3-3k-1)+r^3k^2(4k^2-12k+16)\\&+r^2k^2(-12k^2-12k+16) -16k^4(2r+1))\\&+nk(r^4(-8k^2+4k+4)+r^3k^2(-8k-4)+r^2k^3(-8k-4))\\&+4k^2r^2(r^2(k-1)+k^2(1+r))\text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Thus, there exists \({\bar{n}}>0\), such that for any \(n>{\bar{n}}\), it holds that \(p(n)<0\) which concludes the proof. \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 4.2:

First, for simplicity, we assume that the size s of cartel S is a real number in the interval \([1,n-1]\). Then, differentiating \(\pi _i^C(q_s^*,{\tilde{q}}_s)\) with respect to s leads to:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d}{ds}\pi _i^C(q_s^*,{\tilde{q}}_s)=\frac{V^2nr^2(1+r)(2n+r)^2(3rs^2-(r(n+2)-2n)s-2n)}{(4n^2+2rn(1+n)+rs((n+2)r+2n)-r^2s^2)^3}\text{. } \end{aligned}$$

We aim to study the polynomial function of degree 2, \(p:[1,n-1] \longrightarrow {\mathbb {R}}\), defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} p(s)=3rs^2-(r(n+2)-2n)s-2n\text{. } \end{aligned}$$

The discriminant of p(s) is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta = (n+2)^2r^2+(16n-4n^2)r+4n^2\text{, } \end{aligned}$$

and is positive for any \(n\ge 3\) and any \(r>0\). Hence, p(s) has two distinct real roots:

$$\begin{aligned} s_{1,2}= \frac{r(n+2)-2n \pm \sqrt{(n+2)^2r^2+(16n-4n^2)r+4n^2}}{6r}\text{. } \end{aligned}$$

We want to prove that \(s_1<0\) and \(1<s_2<n-1\). We proceed in three steps.

First, we distinguish two cases. If \(r(n+2)-2n \ge 0\), then:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} s_1&= \frac{\sqrt{(r(n+2)-2n)^2}-\sqrt{(n+2)^2r^2+(16n-4n^2)r+4n^2}}{6r}\\&= \frac{\sqrt{(n+2)^2r^2+(-8n-4n^2)r+4n^2}-\sqrt{(n+2)^2r^2 +(16n-4n^2)r+4n^2}}{6r}\\&<0 \text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Otherwise, if \(r(n+2)-2n < 0\), then we can easily verify that \(s_1<0\).

Second, it holds that:

$$\begin{aligned} s_2-1= \frac{r(n-4)-2n + \sqrt{(n+2)^2r^2+(16n-4n^2)r+4n^2}}{6r}\text{. } \end{aligned}$$

We distinguish two cases. If \(r(n-4)-2n \le 0\), then:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} s_2-1&= \frac{-\sqrt{(2n-r(n-4))^2} +\sqrt{(n+2)^2r^2+(16n-4n^2)r+4n^2}}{6r}\\&= \frac{-\sqrt{(n-4)^2r^2+(16n-4n^2)r+4n^2}+\sqrt{(n+2)^2r^2 +(16n-4n^2)r+4n^2}}{6r}\\&>0 \text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Otherwise, if \(r(n-4)-2n > 0\), then we can easily verify that \(s_2-1>0\).

Third, it holds that:

$$\begin{aligned} n-1-s_2= \frac{r(5n-8)+2n- \sqrt{(n+2)^2r^2+(16n-4n^2)r+4n^2}}{6r}\text{. } \end{aligned}$$

We distinguish two cases. If \(n=3\), then:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} 2-s_2&= \frac{7r+6-\sqrt{25r^2+12r+36}}{6r}\\&= \frac{\sqrt{49r^2+84r+36}-\sqrt{25r^2+12r+36}}{6r}\\&>0 \text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Otherwise, if \(n \ge 4\), then:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} n-1-s_2&\ge \frac{r(5n-8)+2n - \sqrt{(n+2)^2r^2+4n^2}}{6r}\\&> \frac{r(5n-8)+2n - \sqrt{(n+2)^2r^2}-\sqrt{4n^2}}{6r}\\&=\frac{4n-10}{6}\\&>0 \text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

It follows from the above three steps that p(s) is strictly decreasing in the interval \([1,s_2]\) and strictly increasing in the interval \([s_2,n-1]\). This implies that \(\pi _i^C(q_s^*,{\tilde{q}}_s)\) attains its maximum either at \(s=1\) or at \(s=n-1\) which proves the first part of Lemma 4.2.

It remains to compare the two following profits of each cartel member derived from (22):

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^C(q_1^*,{\tilde{q}}_1)=\frac{V^2n(1+r)(n+r)}{(2n+r(n+1))^2}\text{, } \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1})=\frac{V^2n(1+r)(2n+r)^2(n+r(n-1))}{(4n^2(1+r)+3r^2(n-1))^2}\text{. } \end{aligned}$$

Calculating the difference between these two individual profits leads to:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&\pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1})- \pi _i^C(q_1^*,{\tilde{q}}_1) =V^2n(n-2)r^2(1+r) \\&\quad \times \frac{(n^2-6n+5)r^3+(4n^3-16n^2+8n)r^2 +(4n^4-8n^3-4n^2)r+4n^4-8n^3}{(2n+r(1+n))^2(3r^2(n-1)+4n^2(1+r))^2} \text{. }\end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

We can verify that \(\pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1})- \pi _i^C(q_1^*,{\tilde{q}}_1)\) is positive for any \(n\ge 5\).Footnote 12 We conclude that for any \(s\in \lbrace {1,\ldots ,n-2}\rbrace \), \(\pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1})>\pi _i^C(q_s^*,{\tilde{q}}_s)\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 4.3:

It follows from (7) that a Cournot oligopoly TU-game \((N,v^C )\in G\) is balanced, and so has a non-empty core, if and only if \(v^C(N)\ge v_R^C(N)\) where \((N,v_R^C )\) is the root game of \((N,v^C )\). Furthermore, we deduce from Lemma 4.2 that the worth of the grand coalition \(v_R^C(N)\) is obtained either at the balanced collection \(\lbrace {\lbrace {k}\rbrace :k\in N}\rbrace \) or at the balanced collection \(\lbrace {N\backslash {\lbrace {k}\rbrace } : k\in N}\rbrace \). Hence, it holds that:

$$\begin{aligned} v_R^C(N)=n\max \left\{ \pi _i^C(q_{1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{1}),\pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1}).\right\} \end{aligned}$$
(23)

It remains to show that \(\pi _i^C(q_{n}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n})\ge \max \lbrace {\pi _i^C(q_{1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{1}),\pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1}})\rbrace \). Using the expression of Nash equilibrium profit of any cartel member in Cournot competition given by (22), one gets:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i^C(q_{n}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n})-\pi _i^C(q_{1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{1})&= \frac{(Vr(n-1))^2}{4(r(1+n)+2n)^2} \\&>0\text{, } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i^C(q_{n}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n})-\pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1})&= \frac{V^2r^2((5n^2-14n+9)r^2+(8n^3-16n^2+4n)r+8n^3-12n^2)}{4(3r^2(n-1)+4n^2(1+r))^2} \\&>0\text{. } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Hence, we conclude that \(v^C(N)\ge v_R^C(N)\) which is equivalent to \(C(N,v^C )\ne \emptyset \). \(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 4.5:

First, we determine the aggregate-monotonic cores of \((N,v^B)\in G\) and \((N,v^C)\in G\) respectively. It follows from Theorem 4.4 that the worth of the grand coalition \(v_R^B(N)\) is obtained at the balanced collection \(\lbrace {N\backslash {\lbrace {k}\rbrace } : k\in N}\rbrace \). Hence, it holds that:

$$\begin{aligned} v_R^B(N)=n\pi _i^B(p_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{p}}_{n-1}), \end{aligned}$$
(24)

where \((N,v_R^B)\) is the root game of \((N,v^B)\). Moreover, since oligopoly TU-games \((N,v^B)\) and \((N,v^C)\) are symmetric, the cores of their associated root games \(C(N,v_R^B)\) and \(C(N,v_R^C)\), respectively, are singletons.Footnote 13 We deduce from (23) and (24) that:

$$\begin{aligned} C(N,v_R^B)=\left\{ (\pi _i^B(p_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{p}}_{n-1}))_{i=1}^n\right\} \text{, } \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} C(N,v_R^C)=\Big \{( \max \Big \{ \pi _i^C(q_{1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{1}),\pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1})\Big \})_{i=1}^n\Big \}. \end{aligned}$$

It follows from (8) that:

$$\begin{aligned} AC(N,v^B)=\lbrace {(\pi _i^B(p_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{p}}_{n-1}))_{i=1}^n + (v^B(N)-n\pi _i^B(p_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{p}}_{n-1}))\cdot \Delta _n }\rbrace \text{, } \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} AC(N,v^C)&=\lbrace {(\max \lbrace {\pi _i^C(q_{1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{1}),\pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*, {\tilde{q}}_{n-1}})\rbrace )_{i=1}^n} \\&{+(v^C(N)-n\max \lbrace {\pi _i^C(q_{1}^*, {\tilde{q}}_{1}),\pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1})}\rbrace ) \cdot \Delta _n }\rbrace \text{, } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

where \(\Delta _n\) denotes the unit-simplex.

Second, since \(v^B(N)=v^C(N)\) it is sufficient to show that \(\pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1}) > \pi _i^B(p_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{p}}_{n-1})\) to establish that \(AC(N,v^C)\subset AC(N,v^B)\). Using the expressions of Nash equilibrium profits of any cartel member in Bertrand and Cournot competition given by (19) and (22), one gets:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \pi _i^C(q_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{q}}_{n-1})-\pi _i^B(p_{n-1}^*,{\tilde{p}}_{n-1})&=\frac{V^2nr^3(n-1)(2+r)}{(3r^2(n-1)+4n^2(1+r))^2}\\&>0\text{, } \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

which concludes the proof. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lardon, A. On the coalitional stability of monopoly power in differentiated Bertrand and Cournot oligopolies. Theory Decis 87, 421–449 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-019-09720-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-019-09720-9

Keywords

Navigation