Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Executive Compensation and Employee Remuneration: The Flexible Principles of Justice in Pay

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates a series of normative principles that are used to justify different aspects of executive compensation within business firms, as well as the remuneration of lower-ranking employees. We look at how businesses perform pay benchmarking; employees’ engagement, fidelity and loyalty (and their effects on pay practices); and the acceptability of what we call both-ends-dipping, that is, receiving both ex ante and ex post benefits for the same work. We make two observations. First, either different or incoherent principles are used to justify the pay of executives compared to employees, or the same principles are applied differently. Second, these differences or inconsistencies tend to be to the benefit of executives and/or to the detriment of employees. We conclude by asking whether there is any reason for thinking differently about executive pay than we do about employee pay. Our analysis leads us to question the principles justifying current executive compensation and to wonder if these principles are potentially being instrumentalized to serve other ends.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for instance, Frydman and Jenter (2010), Frydman and Saks (2010), Allaire (2012), St-Onge (2014) and a report in the Harvard Business Review (2014). In recent years, the emphasis has been on incentive compensation rather than cash salary. Damodaran (2015), relying on data from Compustat Execucomp, finds that 70% of the typical CEO compensation package in 2013 is equity-based, with cash compensation (salary and cash bonuses) trailing at less than 25%. See also Anderson and Klinger (2016) on the evolution of inequalities regarding retirement plans of CEOs in comparison with employees. The work of Piketty (2014) on inequality is also relevant in this respect.

  2. Equity-based compensation to non-executive employees is on the way out. In the decade leading up to 2010, the number of US employees with stock options declined by a third, to less than 9%. The decline has been even more dramatic in the innovation/high-tech sector, with the percentages of employees having an equity interest in their employer dropping from around 60% to less than 20% (Blasi 2017; Chasan 2013).

  3. Moriarty (2006) refers to ‘the agreement view,’ but we will use these two views interchangeably for the purposes of this paper. A view based on the value of an agreement largely overlaps with a view based on the value of freedom. More generally, notions such as freedom, agreement, consent, coercion, voluntariness, independence, being informed about one’s choices, autonomy, etc. are closely connected with each other. It is often hard to define one of these notions without using the other. For instance, Shaw (2006, 97) uses the notion of an agreement to define the notion of libertarian freedom. This is consistent with the definition we provide above, with free agreement being a condition for just executive pay.

  4. Or consider these other difficult questions that a board may have to answer if it wants to pay an executive according to the efficiency view: Is executive pay efficient as soon as an executive increases value creation for a firm above its cost to that firm? Or must an executive maximize value creation at a given cost? What if a CEO B can create more value than a CEO A, yet has the same cost in terms of their compensation package? Or what if CEO B can create as much value as CEO A, but for a smaller cost? When boards are hiring CEOs, they will consider which candidate is the most likely to create the most value, and this will influence the compensation package that will be offered.

  5. As an example of the force of judgments about deservingness, consider that workers who are less well remunerated often end up under-performing because they feel that they are deprived of what they, too, deserve (Cowherd and Levine 1992). The phenomenon has also been observed among top executives, where high inequalities in levels of compensation may have an impact on performance (Fredrickson et al. 2010).

  6. Consistent with an efficiency view, Boatright (2010, p. 190) claims that executive compensation is justified ‘if it is the result from arm’s-length bargaining,’ with the ultimate aim of this bargaining being ‘maximum wealth creation for shareholders.’ However, his view rests on ‘the justness of a free market capitalist system’ and the ‘relevant ethical principles’ people accept within the system, such as enforcing property rights for freely exchanging goods and services (171 ff.). Boatright even draws a connection between his conception of justice in pay and Nozick’s entitlement theory, thus reinforcing the impression that he considers the preservation of economic freedom as critical. Boatright also claims that there is consensus in the USA on these views, as they are embodied in business laws, market regulations and even general public views. At this point, it becomes unclear whether he endorses the efficiency or the freedom view.

  7. Executive compensation cannot be efficient if firms and executives do not have the necessary freedom to negotiate their employment agreements—if, say, governments imposes labor laws that are too strict or intervene in the labor market in other ways. This is why the market is considered to be preferable to other, more bureaucratic arrangements for organizing economic activities (e.g., Buchanan 1985; Legrand and Bartlett 1993).

  8. For example, advocating less regulation and more economic freedom on executive compensation questions can be viewed as the best way to ensure efficiency in the market. Here, freedom is defended instrumentally, rather than being considered valuable in itself. But it implies that economic freedom may be constrained as soon as it is shown that more freedom will not increase efficiency. Regulations can be imposed on the labor market if, for instance, market failures or distortions need to be corrected. Such interventions may be more difficult to justify under the freedom view.

  9. The compensation literature refers to internal and external equity, with equity appreciation essentially resting on benchmarking considerations.

  10. Albuquerque et al. (2013) provide a different perspective. While they acknowledge that most prior research seems to show that firms are more likely to compare themselves with comparable firms that pay their CEOs better, they question the conclusion that this serves the interest of CEOs and other executives. Instead, their findings suggest that the upward bias in compensation resulting from the peer group selection is more likely to reflect a reward for unobserved CEO talent, rather than self-serving behavior. Referring to Holmstrom and Kaplan (2003) and Bizjak et al. (2008), they conclude that the effect of peer benchmarking on CEO pay is more likely to reflect tighter managerial labor markets than weak governance.

  11. https://blog.mercerpeoplepro.com/salary-compensation-benchmarking-101/. Retrieved November 8, 2017.

  12. http://www.haygroup.com/ca/services/index.aspx?id=6555. Retrieved November 8, 2017.

  13. Scott et al. (2011) also find that employees in large firms are more likely to highlight concerns about the fairness of remuneration than employees of small firms. These findings are somewhat puzzling, as larger firms typically have more formally developed reward programs, policies and structures. One may wonder if the publicly disclosed compensation packages of senior executives at large firms do not contribute to increased concerns about fairness in such firms. In any case, Scott et al. also recommend that large firms pay even more attention to the perceived fairness of their pay practices, which includes a better understanding of the employee perspective in reward program values.

  14. Some firms do refer to internal equity in describing their executive compensation practices (e.g., JPMorgan Chase). However, in contrast to benchmarking, whose mechanics are typically well described with specific objectives or targets, references to internal equity with lower-level employees are typically rather vague.

  15. See Kahn (1990). There are several other definitions of employee engagement being circulated (for instance, by firms such as the Corporate Leadership Council). The above definition only provides a template for analysis.

  16. Firms face a major challenge as the estimated cost arising from poor employee engagement is huge, see Sorenson and Garman (2013).

  17. Macroeconomic data point toward low salary growth in the USA, Canada and the UK despite consistent economic growth, an outcome that is consistent with firms taking measures to lower their labor costs. For example, see The Economist, Why American wage growth is so lousy (April 14, 2015) at https://www.economist.com/blogs/economist-explains/2015/04/economist-explains-12. Retrieved November 8, 2017.

  18. The saga is not over yet. On March 6, 2017, CSX, a large US railway firm, announced that it had appointed Mr. Harrison as its CEO (Atkins 2017).

  19. Overall data from the Conference Board suggest that the average tenure for CEOs of Standard & Poor’s 500 firms has fluctuated at around 9 years since the early 2000 s, with a low of 7.2 years during the financial crisis in 2009 and a high of 11.3 years in 2002. However, these figures are sensitive to extreme cases: For instance, for 2014, the average tenure is 9.9 years for CEOs of Standard & Poor’s 500 firms, but only 9.0 years if we exclude the retirement of two long-serving CEOs (Larry Ellison of Oracle, with 37 years, and Peter Rose of Expeditors International, with 26 years).

  20. Moriarty (2005, p. 258) makes a similar distinction when he writes that what he calls the utility view, as opposed to the desert view, ‘conceives of wages not as rewards for past work, but as incentives for future work.’

  21. One may point out that executives get something like a ‘welcome to the firm’ bonus and something like a ‘see you later’ bonus, but both bonuses are negotiated up front. Therefore, there would be just one ‘dip’ at the beginning, and this practice would be consistent with the efficiency view. This scenario is certainly plausible. Ex ante and ex post benefits may be negotiated up front in some cases. But it must not be forgotten that ex post benefits do not only involve pay severance packages or retirement plans. They also include ad hoc bonuses that are not negotiated up front. Therefore, there are still many scenarios wherein the dipping-from-both-ends phenomenon may occur.

  22. See, for instance, McMahon (2013) and Néron (2015).

  23. For an overview of the research on culture and business pay practices, see the work of Hofstede et al. (2010), Greckhamer (2011, 2016) and Boeri et al. (2013).

  24. To illustrate further, the magnitude of executive compensation relative to firms’ earnings has increased from around 5% in 1993–1995 to around 10% in 2001–2003 (Bebchuk and Grinstein 2005; Sur et al. 2015, p. 31). From 1978 to 2011, the increase in CEO compensation, which can be put at more than 725% according to some estimates, is substantially greater than stock market and corporate earnings growth (Mishel and Sabadish 2012).

  25. Piketty (2014, p. 331) points out, for instance, that there is no objective basis for high executive compensation, because the job function is unique and not replicable, which makes it ‘something close to a pure ideological construct’ and, therefore, more likely to be influenced by cultural perceptions.

References

  • Albrecht, S. L. (2011). Handbook of employee engagement: Perspectives, issues, research and practice. Human Resource Management International Digest, 19(7), 3–19.

  • Albuquerque, A. M., De Franco, G., & Verdi, R. S. (2013). Peer choice in CEO compensation. Journal of Financial Economics, 108(1), 160–181.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. The American Economic Review, 62(5), 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allaire, Y. (2012). Pay for value: Cutting the Gordian knot of executive compensation. Montréal, QC: Institute for the Governance of Private and Public Firms.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allaire, Y., & Dauphin, F. (2015). How Pershing square found success at Canadian Pacific Railway. Financial Post, Toronto, ON. Retrieved from http://business.financialpost.com/fp-comment/how-pershing-square-found-success-at-canadian-pacific-railway.

  • Anderson, J. (2008). Stock exchange’s ex-chief wins battle to keep pay. The New York Times, New York, NY. Retrieved from http://www.nytimes.com/2008/07/02/business/02grasso.html.

  • Anderson, S., & Klinger, S. (2016). A tale of two retirements: As working families face rising retirement insecurity. CEOs enjoy platinum pensions, Institute for Policy Studies, Washington, DC. Retrieved from http://www.ips-dc.org/report-tale-two-retirements.

  • Atkins, E. (2017). Hunter Harrison joins CSX Corp. as CEO. The Globe and Mail, Toronto, ON.

  • Atkinson, A. B. (2015). Inequality: What can be done?. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bal, P. M., Kooij, D. T. A. M., & De Jong, S. B. (2013). How do developmental and accommodative HRM enhance employee engagement and commitment? The role of psychological contract and SOC strategies. Journal of Management Studies, 50(4), 545–572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrick, M. R., Thurgood, G. R., Smith, T. A., & Courtright, S. H. (2015). Collective organizational engagement: Linking motivational antecedents, strategic implementation, and firm performance. Academy of Management Journal, 58(1), 111–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L. A., Cremers, K. J. M., & Peyer, U. C. (2011). The CEO pay slice. Journal of Financial Economics, 102(1), 199–221.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L. A., & Fried, J. (2006). Pay without performance: The unfulfilled promise of executive compensation (1st ed.). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L. A., & Grinstein, Y. (2005). The growth of executive pay. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 21(2), 283–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bizjak, J. M., Lemmon, M. L., & Naveen, L. (2008). Does the use of peer groups contribute to higher pay and less efficient compensation? Journal of Financial Economics, 90(2), 152–168.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bizjak, J., Lemmon, M., & Nguyen, T. (2011). Are all CEOs above average? An empirical analysis of compensation peer groups and pay design. Journal of Financial Economics, 100(3), 538–555.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blasi, J. (2017). Tech companies are shutting employees out of the stock market’s boom. Fortune Magazine. Retrieved from http://fortune.com/2017/04/12/tech-stock-market/.

  • Boatright, J. R. (2010). Executive compensation: Unjust or just right? In G. G. Brenkert & T. L. Beauchamp (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of business ethics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boeri, T., Lucifora, C., & Murphy, K. J. (2013). Executive remuneration and employee performance-related pay: A transatlantic perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, A. E. (1985). Ethics, efficiency and the market. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chasan, E. (2013). Last gasp for stock options? CFO Journal. The Wall Street Journal, New York, NY. Retrieved from https://blogs.wsj.com/cfo/2013/08/26/last-gasp-for-stock-options/.

  • Clifford, S. (2017). The CEO pay machine: How it trashes America and how to stop it. New York, NY: Penguin Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cole, M. S., Walter, F., Bedeian, A. G., & O’Boyle, E. H. (2012). Job burnout and employee engagement: A meta-analytic examination of construct proliferation. Journal of Management, 38(5), 1550–1581.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conyon, M. J., Peck, S. I., & Sadler, G. V. (2009). Compensation consultants and executive pay: Evidence from the United States and the United Kingdom. Academy of Management Perspectives, 23(1), 43–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowen, A. P., King, A. W., & Marcel, J. J. (2016). CEO severance agreements: A theoretical examination and research agenda. Academy of Management Review, 41(1), 151–169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cowherd, D. M., & Levine, D. I. (1992). Product quality and pay equity between lower-level employees and top management: An investigation of distributive justice theory. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37(2), 302–320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Damodaran, A. (2015). CEO compensation: The pricing and valuing of top managers! ValueWalk, New York, NY. Retrieved from http://www.valuewalk.com/2015/04/ceo-compensation-the-pricing-and-valuing-of-top-managers.

  • Di Prete, T. A., Eirich, G. M., & Pittinsky, M. (2010). Compensation benchmarking, leapfrogs, and the surge in executive pay. American Journal of Sociology, 115(6), 1671–1712.

    Google Scholar 

  • El-Hajji, M. A. (2015). The Hay system of job evaluation: A critical analysis. Journal of Human Resources, 3(1), 1–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eyal, N. (2012). Informed consent. In E. N. Zalta (Ed.), The Stanford encyclopedia of philosophy. Retrieved from http://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2012/entries/informed-consent.

  • Faulkender, M., & Yang, J. (2010). Inside the black box: The role and composition of compensation peer groups. Journal of Financial Economics, 96(2), 257–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feinberg, J. (1970). Doing & deserving: Essays in the theory of responsibility. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, F., & Skow, B. (2015). Desert. In E. N. Zalta (Ed.), The Stanford encyclopedia of philosophy. Retrieved from http://plato.stanford.edu/archives/win2015/entries/desert.

  • Fiss, P. C. (2007). A set-theoretic approach to organizational configurations. Academy of Management Review, 32(4), 1180–1198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fredrickson, J. W., Davis-Blake, A., & Sanders, W. G. (2010). Sharing the wealth: Social comparisons and pay dispersion in the CEO’s top team. Strategic Management Journal, 31(10), 1031–1053.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frydman, C., & Jenter, D. (2010). CEO compensation. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 2(1), 75–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frydman, C., & Saks, R. E. (2010). Executive compensation: A new view from a long-term perspective, 1936–2005. Review of Financial Studies, 23(5), 2099–2138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gao, H., Luo, J., & Tang, T. (2015). Effects of managerial labor market on executive compensation: Evidence from job-hopping. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 59(2), 203–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghoshal, S. (2005). Bad management theories are destroying good management practices. Academy of Management Learning & Education, 4(1), 75–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greckhamer, T. (2011). Cross-cultural differences in compensation level and inequality across occupations: A set-theoretic analysis. Organization Studies, 32(1), 85–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greckhamer, T. (2016). CEO compensation in relation to worker compensation across countries: The configurational impact of country-level institutions. Strategic Management Journal, 37(4), 793–815.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gross, S. E., & Rook, M. (2015). Using a total rewards strategy to achieve competitive advantage. In L. A. Berger & D. R. Berger (Eds.), The compensation handbook (pp. 13–26). New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harman, G. (1975). Moral relativism defended. The Philosophical Review, 84(1), 3–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, J. D. (2006). How much is too much? A theoretical analysis of executive compensation from the standpoint of distributive justice. In R. W. Kolb (Ed.), The ethics of executive compensation (pp. 67–86). Malden, MA: Wiley-Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvard Business Review. (2014). The whys and wherefores of executive pay. Harvard Business Review, 92(7/8), 32–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hermalin, B. E. (2005). Trends in corporate governance. The Journal of Finance, 60(5), 2351–2384.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hewitt, A. (2012). 2012 Trends in global employee engagement. Aon Corporation.

  • Himmelberg, C. P., & Hubbard, R. G. (2000). Incentive pay and the market for CEOs: An analysis of pay-for-performance sensitivity. New York, NY: Columbia University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofstede, G. H., Hofstede, G. J., & Minkov, M. (2010). Cultures and firms: Software of the mind: Intercultural cooperation and its importance for survival. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B. (1979). Moral hazard and observability. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 74–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. The Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 324–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., & Kaplan, S. N. (2003). The state of US corporate governance: What’s right and what’s wrong? Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15(3), 8–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1991). Multitask principal-agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 7, 24–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jeffrey, S. (2004). The benefits of tangible non-monetary incentives. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago, Graduate School of Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jeffrey, S. A. (2009). Justifiability and the motivational power of tangible noncash incentives. Human Performance, 22(2), 143–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990a). Performance pay and top-management incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 98(2), 225–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990b). CEO incentives: It’s not how much you pay, but how. Harvard Business Review, 68(3), 138–149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., Murphy, K. J., & Wruck, E. G. (2004). Remuneration: Where we’ve been, how we got to here, what are the problems, and how to fix them. Finance working paper, European Corporate Governance Institute, Brussels, Belgium.

  • Kahn, W. A. (1990). Psychological conditions of personal engagement and disengagement at work. Academy of Management Journal, 33(4), 692–724.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (2008). Choices, values and frames (p. 840). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khurana, R. (2007). From higher aims to hired hands: The social transformation of American business schools and the unfulfilled promise of management as a profession. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolb, R. W. (2012). Too much is not enough: Incentives in executive compensation. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krausz, M. (1989). Relativism: Interpretation and confrontation. IN: University of Notre Dame Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krausz, M. (2010). Relativism: A contemporary anthology. New York, NY: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert, R. A. (2001). Contracting theory and accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 32(1), 3–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laurentian Bank of Canada. (2016). Management proxy circular. Montréal, QC: Laurentian Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Le Grand, J. (1990). Equity versus efficiency: The elusive trade-off. Ethics, 100(3), 554–568.

    Google Scholar 

  • Legrand, J., & Bartlett, W. (1993). Quasi-markets and social policy. London: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leinwand, P., & Mainardi, C. (2010). The coherence premium. Harvard Business Review, Boston, MA. Retrieved from https://hbr.org/2010/06/the-coherence-premium.

  • McMahon, C. (2013). Public capitalism: The political authority of corporate executives. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milkovich, G. T., Newman, J. M., & Gerhart, B. A. (2014). Compensation (11th ed.). New York, NY: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mintzberg, H. (1982). A note on that dirty word efficiency. Interfaces, 12(5), 101–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishel, L., & Sabadish, N. (2012). CEO pay and the top 1%: How executive compensation and financial-sector pay have fueled income inequality. Washington, DC: Issue brief, Economic Policy Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishel, L., & Schieder, J. (2017). CEO pay remains high relative to the pay of typical workers and high-wage earners. Report, Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC.

  • Mone, E., Eisinger, C., Guggenheim, K., Price, B., & Stine, C. (2011). Performance management at the wheel: Driving employee engagement in firms. Journal of Business and Psychology, 26(2), 205–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moriarty, J. (2005). Do CEOs get paid too much? Business Ethics Quarterly, 15(2), 257–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moriarty, J. (2006). How to (try to) justify CEO pay. In R. W. Kolb (Ed.), The ethics of executive compensation. Malden, MA: Wiley-Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, M. (2015). The big number. Wall Street Journal, New York, NY. Retrieved from http://www.wsj.com/articles/the-big-number-1445904434.

  • Murphy, K. J., & Zabojnik, J. (2004). CEO pay and appointments: A market-based explanation for recent trends. The American Economic Review, 94(2), 192–196.

    Google Scholar 

  • Néron, P.-Y. (2015). Egalitarianism and executive compensation: A relational argument. Journal of Business Ethics, 132(1), 171–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nozick, R. (1974). Anarchy, state, and utopia. New York, NY: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olsaretti, S. (2004). Liberty, desert and the market: A philosophical study. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oyer, P. (2004). Why do firms use incentives that have no incentive effects? The Journal of Finance, 59(4), 1619–1650.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century (A. Goldhammer, Trans.). Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

  • Rajgopal, S., Taylor, D., & Venkatachalam, M. (2012). Frictions in the CEO labor market: The role of talent agents in CEO compensation. Contemporary Accounting Research, 29(1), 119–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rich, B. L., Lepine, J. A., & Crawford, E. R. (2010). Job engagement: Antecedents and effects on job performance. Academy of Management Journal, 53(3), 617–635.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saks, A. M. (2006). Antecedents and consequences of employee engagement. Journal of Managerial Psychology, 21(7), 600–619.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schellhardt, T. D. (1998). Executive pay (A special report): Pay checks. They show them the money: Lawyer-agents like Robert J. Stucker help executives win the big bucks—And not overlook the fine print. New York, NY: The Wall Street Pub.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1942). Creative destructionCapitalism, socialism and democracy (Vol. 825). Reedited by Routledge, May 13, 2013.

  • Scott, D., McMullen, T., & Royal, M. (2011). Reward fairness. Scottsdale AR: Report, WorldatWork.

    Google Scholar 

  • Securities and Exchange Commission. (2006). Final rules 33-8732a, Item 402(b)(2)(xiv). Washington, D.C.

  • Shaw, W. H. (2006). Justice, incentives, and executive compensation. In R. W. Kolb (Ed.), The ethics of executive compensation (pp. 87–100). Malden, MA: Wiley-Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sorenson, S., & Garman, K. (2013). How to tackle U.S. employees’ stagnating engagement. Gallup, Washington. Retrieved from Gallup http://news.gallup.com/businessjournal/162953/tackle-employees-stagnating-engagement.aspx.

  • Spencer Stuart. (2016). U.S. Board Index. New York. Retrieved from: https://www.spencerstuart.com/~/media/pdf%20files/research%20and%20insight%20pdfs/spencer-stuart-us-board-index-2016_1mar2017.pdf.

  • Stadler, C. (2015). How to become a CEO: These are the steps you should take. Forbes Magazine, New York, NY. Retrieved from https://www.forbes.com/sites/christianstadler/2015/03/12/how-to-become-a-ceo-these-are-the-steps-you-should-take/#4016d7ce1217.

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). The great divide: Unequal societies and what we can do about them. New York, NY: W. W. Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • St-Onge, S. (2014). Gestion de la rémunération—Théorie et pratique. Montréal, QC: Chenelière Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sur, S., Magnan, M., & Cordeiro, J. (2015). Disentangling CEO compensation: A simultaneous examination of time, industry, and firm-level effects. Canadian Journal of Administrative Sciences/Revue Canadienne des Sciences de l’Administration, 32(1), 30–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomasello, M. (1999). The cultural origins of human cognition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomasi, J. (2012). Free market fairness. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Technologies Corporation. (2016). Annual proxy statement. Farmington, CT: United Technologies Corporation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Dyke, M. (2015). Base salary: Using non-monetary awards to support behaviors that drive business results. The compensation handbook: A state-of-the-art guide to compensation strategy and design (pp. 143–156). New York: McGraw-Hill.

  • Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies, analysis and antitrust implications: A study in the economics of internal organization. New York, NY: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1981). The economics of organization: The transaction cost approach. American Journal of Sociology, 87, 548–577.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to acknowledge financial support from the Stephen A. Jarislowsky Chair in Corporate Governance, the Institute for the Governance of Private and Public Organizations, and the Mitacs Accelerate program.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dominic Martin.

Ethics declarations

Ethical Approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Magnan, M., Martin, D. Executive Compensation and Employee Remuneration: The Flexible Principles of Justice in Pay. J Bus Ethics 160, 89–105 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-018-3786-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-018-3786-5

Keywords

Navigation