Skip to main content

Institutions, Growth, and Inequality in Ancient Greece

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Democracy, Justice, and Equality in Ancient Greece

Part of the book series: Philosophical Studies Series ((PSSP,volume 132))

  • 1406 Accesses

Abstract

The characterization of the world of the ancient Greek city states as relatively poor and economically static has been refuted by recent advances in Greek economic history. The Greek world grew dramatically, compared to other premodern societies, both in population and per capita consumption from the age of Homer to that of Aristotle. By the fourth century BCE the city-state ecology was densely populated, and median consumption was well above bare subsistence. Athenian income inequality can be roughly measured using income and population estimates from late fourth century BCE. This paper argues that, at least in Athens, economic growth was accompanied by historically low levels of income inequality. Both economic growth and low inequality are explained by the development of citizen-centered political institutions. Growth, inequality, and institutions were important parts of the historical context in which Plato and Aristotle wrote. Attending to that context may elucidate some aspects of Greek political philosophy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a comprehensive survey of inequality in world history, see now Scheidel (2017). Some of the material in this chapter is adapted and updated from chapters 4 and 5 of Ober (2015a). Section 2.3 offers an abbreviated survey of results reported more fully in Ober (2017). I am indebted to Claire Taylor, Ian Morris , Walter Scheidel , Mirko Canevaro, David Lewis, Rob Fleck, Andy Hanssen, and Federica Carugati and to the organizers and participants in the UC San Diego conference for discussions and shared work in progress related to the issues addressed in this paper.

  2. 2.

    In addition to Ober (2015a), recent and important books addressing Greek economic growth in the classical era include Acton (2014), Bresson (2016), and Harris et al. (2015). Taylor (2017) addresses the questions of poverty and well-being in the context of income inequality in classical Athens.

  3. 3.

    I have discussed the evidence for and literature on Greek economic growth in Ober (2010a, 2015a), with references cited. Key growth proxies were developed by Morris (2004).

  4. 4.

    Hanson (2017), the most complete and up-to-date survey, suggests higher rates of urbanization than earlier estimates of 10–11% by Wilson (2009, 2011). Premodern comparisons: Milanovic et al. (2011, table 1); see Table 2.2 below.

  5. 5.

    The alternative demographic standard for measuring urbanization is the percentage of total population living in cities over 10,000. Based on de Vries’ (1984, p. 39, table 3.7) figures for European urbanization in 1600 (at the 10,000+ standard), Hellas was comparable to Holland (24.3%: 19 cities; de Vries 1984, table 3.1), which was the most urbanized part of Europe in 1600. Hellas was substantially more urbanized at the 10,000+ standard than any other European region in 1600: Northern Italy = 16.6% (30 cities); Mediterranean = 13.7% (101 cities); Europe overall = 7.6% (220 cities).

  6. 6.

    Population growth leads to substantially lower living standards in most of the cities of Europe in 1500–1800: Allen (2001) and Deaton (2013, pp. 94–95). Disease: Scheidel (2007). Squalid conditions in the advanced economies of England and Holland: Kron (forthcoming). Greek life expectancy: Morris (2004, pp. 714–720), Kron (2005), and Reden (2007, pp. 388–390). Improved life expectancy for those surviving childhood: Morris (2004, p. 715, figure 2)

  7. 7.

    It is important to keep in mind that the overall Gini wealth index for Athenian society as a whole, including slaves and metics, would surely be substantially higher—I cannot say how much higher because I know no way to calculate wealth of metics or slaves. Wealth inequality, as measured by the Gini coefficient, is typically much higher than income inequality, considered below.

  8. 8.

    As Claire Taylor has pointed out to me, Morris misreported the Gini coefficient as 0.382–0.386, whereas it is actually c. 0.48 (taking the figure of 9% owning 35% of the land). But Morris’ general point remains valid. For example, in late eleventh century Song Dynasty China, an era in which real wages were higher and inequality was lower than in other periods in premodern Chinese history, the wealthiest 5% of the population is believed to have controlled 24% of the land and 34.3% of the population was landless, yielding a Gini coefficient of 0.50. Data from Liu (2015, pp. 127–133).

  9. 9.

    The income and population model used here is described in more detail in Ober (2017). It attempts to nuance the model offered in Ober (2015a, table 4.8). The “optimistic” model developed there yielded an income Gini of 0.40.

  10. 10.

    By way of early modern comparisons, Milanovic et al. (2011, table 2) report the income Gini for Tuscany in 1427 = 0.46; Holland in 1561 = 0.56; England and Wales in 1688 = 0.45; France in 1788 = 0.56.

  11. 11.

    See Ober (2015a, especially chapter 4) with the literature cited therein. Premodern comparanda: Scheidel (2010).

  12. 12.

    For Olynthos houses, Kron (2014, p. 129, table 2) estimates the Gini coefficient of inequality at 0.14, considerably lower than later Hellenistic and Roman era Greek cities. Compare Bintliff (2012, chapter 13).

  13. 13.

    Rome: Scheidel and Friesen (2009). Babylon: Jursa (2010).

  14. 14.

    List and Speikermann (2013) demonstrates that a methodological focus on individuals as choice-making agents (in the form of “supervenience individualism”) is compatible with some forms of causal-explanatory “holism” in respect to considering institutions as collective actors. My two hypotheses assume that their compatibility thesis is correct.

  15. 15.

    Emergence and the relationship between micro-level and high-level phenomena: Petitot (2010).

  16. 16.

    My neologistic phrase “rule egalitarianism” (conceptually similar to what North et al. 2009 call “impersonality”) is modeled on the term “rule consequentialism,” commonly used by ethicists. The rule consequentialist focuses on social rules (as opposed to individual acts) that will maximize aggregate welfare (or alternatively, aggregate preference satisfaction).

  17. 17.

    There is, of course, a good deal of specialization in centralized hierarchies—the complex monarchical civilizations of, e.g., Mesopotamia, Egypt, and Persia, would have not been possible without specialists. Yet hierarchies are relatively inefficient in allocating specialist training to individuals across the relevant population based on aptitude and motivation.

  18. 18.

    Bankruptcy laws that limit personal losses, and rules of incorporation that protect individual investors, are familiar modern examples. Patron-client relationships and voluntary associations (e.g., burial societies) provided alternative, civil society, routes to similar ends in some ancient societies.

  19. 19.

    Gallant (1991) assumes high levels of risk aversion on the part of ancient Greek subsistence farmers and suggests possible family risk-buffering strategies, based in part on evidence from subsistence farming in early modern Greece. But, if the arguments presented here are correct, the classical Greek economy was not predicated on the risk-aversion of families of subsistence farmers. Public insurance and risk: Burke (2005), Möller (2007, pp. 375–383), and Ober (2008, pp. 254–258). Mackil (2004) shows how which a somewhat similar risk insurance mechanism operated in some inter-polis relations.

  20. 20.

    This passage is discussed in more detail in Ober (2015a, chapter 7).

  21. 21.

    Strategic calculation based on formal rationality in Greek thought: Ober (2009). Compare North et al. (2009), who emphasize the behavioral implications of individuals being treated impersonally in institutional contexts. Note that I assume here not only formal equality of standing, but also some degree of freedom of choice in respect to occupation. Obviously in practice the extent of free choice varied considerably, but it is the overall effect of differences in opportunities and incentives that produces the result of relatively greater investment in human capital. See also Ober (2012).

  22. 22.

    Whether the women themselves would have concurred with Socrates’ assessment, we cannot say.

  23. 23.

    On the development of theories and practices of expertise in the Greek world, see Pyzyk (2015).

  24. 24.

    Eighth-century egalitarianism: Morris (1987) and Ober (2015a, chapter 6).

  25. 25.

    Greek egalitarianism: Cartledge (1996), Morris (1996), and Raaflaub (1996). Runciman (1990) emphasizes the historically remarkable level of Greek egalitarianism. Foxhall (2002, p. 218), by contrast, regards “substantial inequalities in landholding ” as a “paradox” that “I have never been able to resolve in my own mind.” The paradox arises, of course, if one supposes that egalitarianism requires either equal outcomes or equal opportunities (measured by equal access to all valuable resources). But, per above, rule egalitarianism assumes neither.

  26. 26.

    This sort of investment in political, rather than specifically economic, skills may be a driver of increased use of slaves and other forms of unfree labor (Scheidel 2008, pp. 115–123). On the other hand, Xenophon (Memorabilia. 3.4) points out that that certain skills required for success in private business affairs are also valuable for managing public affairs (see Sobak 2015). Public goods are in general non-rival (i.e., not a fixed quantity, so that that their use is not subject to zero-sum competition) and non-exclusionary (i.e., all relevant persons have free access).

  27. 27.

    Athenian taxation and state finances: Ober (2015a, pp. 243–252, b). Fawcett (2016) is the most complete and up to date discussion of Athenian taxation. Other premodern fiscal regimes: Scheidel and Monson (2015).

  28. 28.

    Numeracy: Netz (2002); banking and credit instruments: Cohen (1992); rhetoric and social networks: Ober (2008, chapter 4).

  29. 29.

    Innovation and growth: Baumol (1993). Energy capture and growth: Morris (2010). Technology in the Greek world: Greene (2000), Oleson (2008), and Schneider (2007). Agriculture: Sallares (1991); industrial production: Acton (2014); mining and hydraulics: van Liefferinge et al. (2013).

  30. 30.

    Federalism: Mackil (2013) and Beck and Funke (2015); spread of democracy: Teegarden (2014).

  31. 31.

    High stakes of inter-state conflict: Ober (2008, pp. 80–84). Thucydides on Corcyra’s civil war: Ober (2000); Thucydides on rational cooperation and competitive advantage: Ober (2010b).

  32. 32.

    Institutions and coordination: Weingast (1997); Greek awareness: Ober (2009, 2012).

  33. 33.

    Greek embrace of novelty: D’Angour (2011), arguing against, especially, van Groningen (1953).

  34. 34.

    Interstate learning among democracies: Teegarden (2014). Among oligarchies: Simonton (2017). Institutional borrowing by non-Greek authoritarian states, especially in the fourth century, and role of mobile experts: Pyzyk (2015) and Ober (2015a, chapter 10).

  35. 35.

    Athens’ imperial coinage policy: Figueira (1998) and Ober (2015a, chapter 8).

  36. 36.

    For more on such modern impediments, see Laitin (2007).

  37. 37.

    Innovative adaptations of the institution of coined money is a good case in point; for some particularly interesting innovations in this domain, see Mackil and van Alfen (2006).

References

  • Acton, P.H. 2014. Poiesis: Manufacturing in classical Athens. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R.C. 2001. The great divergence in European wages and prices from the middle ages to the First World War. Explorations in Economic History 38: 411–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J. 1993. Entrepreneurship, management, and the structure of payoffs. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, H., and P. Funke, eds. 2015. Federalism in Greek antiquity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bintliff, J. 2012. The complete archaeology of Greece: From hunter-gatherers to the 20th century A.D. Malden: Wiley-Blackwell.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, D.E., D. Canning, and G. Fink. 2008. Urbanization and the wealth of nations. Science 319: 772–775.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C. 2015. Political order and inequality: Their foundations and their consequences for human welfare, Cambridge studies in comparative politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bresson, A. 2016. The making of the ancient Greek economy: Institutions, markets, and growth in the city-states. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burke, E.M. 2005. The habit of subsidization in classical Athens: Toward a Thetic Ideology. Classica et Mediaevalia 56: 5–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cartledge, P. 1996. Comparatively equal. In Dêmokratia: A conversation on democracies, ancient and modern, ed. J. Ober and C.W. Hedrick, 175–186. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, E.E. 1992. Athenian economy and society: A banking perspective. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • D’Angour, A. 2011. The Greeks and the new: Novelty in ancient Greek imagination and experience. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • De Vries, J. 1984. European urbanization 1500–1800. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A. 2013. The great escape: Health, wealth, and the origins of inequality. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fawcett, P. 2016. When I squeeze you with eisphorai. Taxes and tax policy in classical Athens. Hesperia 85: 153–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Figueira, T.J. 1998. The power of money: Coinage and politics in the Athenian empire. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Foxhall, L. 1997. A view from the top: Evaluating the Solonian property classes. In The development of the polis in archaic Greece, ed. L.G. Mitchell and P.J. Rhodes, 113–136. New York: Routledge.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2002. Access to resources in classical Greece: The egalitarianism of the polis in practice. In Money, labour and land: Approaches to the economies of ancient Greece, ed. P. Cartledge, E.E. Cohen, and L. Foxhall, 209–220. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallant, T.W. 1991. Risk and survival in ancient Greece: Reconstructing the rural domestic economy. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. 2002. Efflorescences and economic growth in world history. Journal of World History 13: 323–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, D. 1999. Ants at work: How an insect society is organized. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2010. Ant encounters: Interaction networks and colony behavior. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2014. The ecology of collective behavior. PLoS Biology 12 (3): e1001805.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene, K. 2000. Technical innovation and economic progress in the ancient world: M.I. Finley reconsidered. The Economic History Review 53: 29–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, M.H. 1999. The Athenian democracy in the age of Demosthenes: Structure, principles and ideology. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2006. The shotgun method: The demography of the ancient Greek city-state culture. Columbia: University of Missouri Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, J.W. 2017. An urban geography of the Roman world, 100 BC to AD 300. Oxford: Archaeopress Archaeology.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, E.M., D.M. Lewis, and M. Woolmer, eds. 2015. The ancient Greek economy: markets, households and city-states. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jursa, M. 2010. Aspects of the economic history of Babylonia in the first millennium BC: Economic geography, economic mentalities, agriculture, the use of money and the problem of economic growth. Münster: Ugarit-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, D.P., D. Ratzan, and U. Yiftach-Firanko. 2015. Law and transaction costs in ancient history. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kron, G. 2005. Anthropometry, physical anthropology, and the reconstruction of ancient health, nutrition, and living standards. Historia 54 (1): 68–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2014. Comparative evidence and the reconstruction of the ancient economy: Greco-Roman housing and the level and distribution of wealth and income. In Quantifying the Greco-Roman economy and beyond, ed. F. de Callataÿ, 123–146. Bari: Edipuglia.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. forthcoming. Growth and decline. Forms of growth. Estimating growth in the Greek world. In The Oxford handbook of economies in the classical world, ed. E.L. Cascio, A. Bresson, and F. Velde. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lagia, A. 2015. Diet and the polis: An isotopic study of diet in Athens and Laurion during the Classical, Hellenistic, and Roman periods. In Archaeodiet in the Greek world: Dietary reconstruction from stable isotope analysis (Hesperia Supplement), ed. A. Papathanasiou, M. Richards, and S.C. Fox, 119–146. Princeton: American School of Classical Studies at Athens.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laitin, D.D. 2007. Nations, states, and violence. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • List, C., and K. Spiekermann. 2013. Methodological individualism and holism in political science: A reconciliation. American Political Science Review 107 (4): 629–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, W.G. 2015. The Chinese market economy 1000–1500. Albany: SUNY Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mackil, E. 2004. Wandering cities: Alternatives to catastrophe in the Greek polis. American Journal of Archaeology 108: 493–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2013. Creating a common polity: Religion, economy, and politics in the making of the Greek koinon. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mackil, E., and P.G. van Alfen. 2006. Cooperative coinages. In Agoranomia: Studies in money and exchange presented to John Kroll, ed. P.G. van Alfen, 201–246. New York: American Numismatic Society.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milanovic, B., P.H. Lindert, and J.G. Williamson. 2011. Pre-industrial inequality. The Economic Journal 121 (551): 255–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Möller, A. 2007. Classical Greece: Distribution. In The Cambridge economic history of the Greco-Roman world, ed. W. Scheidel, I. Morris, and R.P. Saller, 362–384. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Morris, I. 1987. Burial and ancient society: The rise of the Greek city-state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1996. The strong principle of equality and the archaic origins of Greek democracy. In Dêmokratia: A conversation on democracies, ancient and modern, ed. J. Ober and C.W. Hedrick, 19–49. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1998. Archaeology as a kind of anthropology (A response to David Small). In Democracy 2500? Questions and challenges, ed. I. Morris and K.A. Raaflaub, 229–239. Dubuque: Kendall/Hunt.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2004. Economic growth in ancient Greece. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 160 (4): 709–742.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2010. Why the West rules—For now: The patterns of history and what they reveal about the future. New York: Farrar, Strauss, and Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Netz, R. 2002. Counter culture: Towards a history of Greek numeracy. History of Science 40 (3): 321–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D.C., J.J. Wallis, and B.R. Weingast. 2009. Violence and social orders. A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ober, J. 2000. Political conflicts, political debates, and political thought. In The shorter Oxford history of Europe I: Classical Greece, ed. R. Osborne, 111–138. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2008. Democracy and knowledge: Innovation and learning in classical Athens. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2009. Public action and rational choice in classical Greek political theory. In A companion to ancient political thought, ed. R.K. Balot, 70–84. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2010a. Thucydides on Athens’ democratic advantage in the Archidamian War. In War, democracy and culture in classical Athens, ed. D. Pritchard, 65–87. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2010b. Wealthy Hellas. Transactions of the American Philological Association 140: 241–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2012. Democracy’s dignity. American Political Science Review 106 (4): 827–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2015a. The rise and fall of classical Athens. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2015b. Classical Athens. In Fiscal regimes and political economy of early states, ed. W. Scheidel and A. Monoson, 492–522. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2017. Inequality in late-classical democratic Athens. Evidence and models. In Democracy and open economy world order, ed. G.C. Bitros and N.C. Kyriazis, 125–146. Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Oleson, J.P. 2008. Oxford handbook of engineering and technology in the classical world. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, R. 1992. Is it a farm? The definition of agricultural sites and settlements in ancient Greece. In Agriculture in Ancient Greece, ed. B. Wells, 22–27. Stockholm: Paul Åströms Förlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petitot, J. 2010. Reduction and emergence in complex systems. In Questioning nineteenth-century assumptions about knowledge: Reductionism (Fernand Braudel Center studies in historical social science), ed. R.F. Lee, 107–159. Binghamton: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pyzyk, M. 2015. Economies of expertise: Knowledge and skill transfer in classical Greece. PhD dissertation. Stanford: Department of Classics, Stanford University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raaflaub, K. 1996. Equalities and inequalities in Athenian democracy. In Dêmokratia: A conversation on democracies, ancient and modern, ed. J. Ober and C.W. Hedrick, 139–174. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Runciman, W.G. 1990. Doomed to extinction: The polis as an evolutionary dead-end. In The Greek city, ed. O. Murray, 348–367. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sallares, R. 1991. The ecology of the ancient Greek world. London: Duckworth.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheidel, W. 2007. Demography. In The Cambridge economic history of the Greco-Roman world, ed. W. Scheidel, I. Morris, and R.P. Saller, 38–86. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2008. The comparative economies of slavery in the Greco-Roman world. In Slave systems: Ancient and modern, ed. E.D. Lago and C. Katsari, 105–126. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2010. Real wages in early economies: Evidence for living standards from 1800 BCE to 1300 CE. Journal of the Social and Economic History of the Orient 53: 425–462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2017. The great leveler. Violence and the global history of inequality from the stone age to the present. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheidel, W., and S.J. Friesen. 2009. The size of the economy and the distribution of income in the Roman Empire. Journal of Romance Studies 99: 61–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheidel, W., and A. Monson, eds. 2015. Fiscal regimes and political economy of premodern states. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, H. 2007. Technology. In The Cambridge economic history of the Greco-Roman world, ed. W. Scheidel, I. Morris, and R.P. Saller, 144–171. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Simonton, M. 2017. Classical Greek oligarchy: A political history. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobak, R. 2015. Sokrates among the Shoemakers. Hesperia 84: 669–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, C. 2017. Poverty, wealth, and well-being: Experiencing penia in democratic Athens. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Teegarden, D. 2014. Death to tyrants! Ancient Greek democracy and the struggle against tyranny. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Groningen, B.A. 1953. In the grip of the past: Essay on an aspect of Greek thought. Leiden: Brill.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • van Liefferinge, K., et al. 2013. Reconsidering the role of Thorikos within the Laurion silver mining area (Attica, Greece) through hydrological analyses. Journal of Archaeological Science 41: 272–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Reden, S. 2007. Consumption. In The Cambridge economic history of the Greco-Roman world, ed. W. Scheidel, I. Morris, and R.P. Saller, 385–406. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B.R. 1997. The political foundations of democracy and the rule of law. American Political Science Review 91: 245–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, A. 2009. Approaches to quantifying Roman trade. In Quantifying the Roman economy: Methods and problems, ed. A.K. Bowman and A. Wilson, 13–49. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2011. City sizes and urbanization in the Roman Empire. In Settlement, urbanization, and population, ed. A.K. Bowman and A. Wilson, 161–193. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Josiah Ober .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Ober, J. (2018). Institutions, Growth, and Inequality in Ancient Greece. In: Anagnostopoulos, G., Santas, G. (eds) Democracy, Justice, and Equality in Ancient Greece. Philosophical Studies Series, vol 132. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-96313-6_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics