Skip to main content
Log in

On the (Sample) Condorcet Efficiency of Majority Rule: An alternative view of majority cycles and social homogeneity

  • Published:
Theory and Decision Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Condorcet efficiency of a social choice procedure is usually defined as the probability that this procedure coincides with the majority winner (or majority ordering) in random samples, given a majority winner exists (or given the majority ordering is transitive). Consequently, it is in effect a conditional probability that two sample statistics coincide, given certain side conditions. We raise a different issue of Condorcet efficiencies: What is the probability that a social choice procedure applied to a sample matches with the majority preferences of the population from which the sample was drawn? We investigate the canonical case where the sample statistic is itself also majority rule and the samples are drawn from real world distributions gathered from national election surveys in Germany, France, and the United States. We relate the results to the existing literature on majority cycles and social homogeneity. We find that these samples rarely display majority cycles, whereas the probability that a sample misrepresents the majority preferences of the underlying population varies dramatically and always exceeds the probability that the sample displays cyclic majority preferences. Social homogeneity plays a fundamental role in the type of Condorcet efficiency investigated here.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

REFERENCES

  • Adams, J.R. and Adams, E.W. (2000), The geometry of voting cycles, Journal of Theoretical Politics 12, 131–153.

    Google Scholar 

  • Balasko, Y. and Cres, H. (1997), The probability of Condorcet cycles and super majority rules. Journal of Economic Theory 75, 237–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berelson, B., Lazarsfeld, P. and McGee, W. (1954), Voting. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1948) On the rationale of group decision-making, Journal of Political Economy 56, 23–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1958), The Theory of Committees and Elections. London and New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brady, H.E. (1990), Dimensional analysis of ranking data, American Journal of Political Science 34(N4), 1017–1048.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brady, H.E. and Ansolabehere, S. (1989), The nature of utility functions in mass publics, American Political Science Review 83(1), 143–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlin, J.R., Cohen, J.L. and Coombs, H.C. (1984), Social choice observed: Five presidential elections of the American Political Science Association, Journal of Politics 45, 479–502.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, L. (1979), Cyclic sets in multidimensional voting models, Journal of Economic Theory 20, 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Condorcet, Marquis de (1785), Essai sur l'Application de l'Analyse à la Probabilité des Décisions Rendues à la Pluralité des Voix.Paris.

  • Dobra, J.L. (1983), An approach to empirical studies of voting paradoxes: An update and extension, Public Choice 41, 241–250.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dobra, J.L. and Tullock, G. (1981), An approach to empirical studies of voting paradoxes, Public Choice 36, 193–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S.L. and Grofman, B. (1986a), On the possibility of faithfully representative committees, American Political Science Review 80(3), 863–879.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S.L. and Grofman, B. (1986b), Partial single-peakedness: An extension and clarification, Public Choice 51, 71–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S.L. and Grofman, B. (1988), Ideological consistency as a collective phenomenon, American Political Science Review 82(3), 64–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S.L. and Grofman, B. (1990), Collectivities as actors, Rationality and Society 2(4), 429–448.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S.L. and Grofman, B. (1992), Who's afraid of the big bad cycle? Journal of Theoretical Politics 4(2), 231–237.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garman, M.B. and Kamien, M.I. (1968), The paradox of voting: Probability calculations, Behavioral Science 13 (July), 306–317.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W.V. (1997), Condorcet's paradox and the Condorcet efficiency of voting rules, Mathematica Japonica 45(1), 173–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W.V. (1999), Condorcet efficiency of Borda rule under the dual culture condition, Social Science Research 28, 36–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W.V. and Fishburn, P.C. (1976a), Condorcet's paradox and anonymous preference profiles, Public Choice 26 (Summer), 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W.V. and Fishburn, P.C. (1976b), The probability of the paradox: A computable solution, Journal of Economic Theory 13 (August), 14–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W.V. and Lepelley, D. (1999), Condorcet efficiencies under the maximal culture condition, Social Choice and Welfare 16, 471–490.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W.V. and Lepelley, D. (2001), The Condorcet efficiency of Borda rule with anonymous voters, Mathematical Social Sciences 41(1), 39–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrlein, W.V. and Valognes, F. (forthcoming), Condorcet efficiency: A preference for indifference, Social Choice and Welfare.

  • Grofman, B. (1975), A comment on democratic theory: A preliminary mathematical model, Public Choice 2l (Spring), 100–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grofman, B. and Uhlaner, C. (1985), Metapreferences and reasons for stability in social choice: Thoughts on broadening and clarifying the debate Theory and Decision 19, 31–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B., Radcliff, B., Taber, C. and Timpone, R. (1995), Condorcet winners and the paradox of voting: probability calculations for weak preference orders. The American Political Science Review 89(1): 137–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klahr, D. (1966), A computer simulation of the paradox of voting, American Political Science Review 60, 384–390.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurrild-Klitgard, P. (2001), An empirical example of the Condorcet paradox of voting for a large electorate, Public Choice, 107(1): 135–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuga, K. and Nugatani, H. (1974), Voter antagonism and the paradox of voting, Econometrica 14 (November), 1045–1067.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lepelley, D., Pierron, P. and Valognes, F. (2000), Scoring rules, Condorcet efficiency and social homogeneity, Theory and Decision 49, 175–196.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luce, R.D. (1956), Semiorders and a theory of utility discrimination, Econometrica 26, 178–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R.D. (1976), Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control, Journal of Economic Theory 12, 472–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R.D. (1979), General conditions for global intransitivities in formal voting models, Econometrica 47, 1085–1112.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R.D. (1986), Covering dominance, and institution free properties of social choice, American Journal of Political Science 30, 283–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N.R., Grofman, B. and Feld, S.L. (1989), The geometry of majority rule, Journal of Theoretical Politics 1, 379–406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R. (1969), Majority decision-making with partial unidimensionality, American Political Science Review 63 (June), 488–497.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R. (1970), The occurrence of the paradox of voting in a university election, Public Choice 8, 91–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R. (1983), Why so much stability? Another opinion, Public Choice 41(2), 261–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R. and Weisberg, H.F. (1968), A mathematical solution for the probability of the paradox of voting Behavioral Science 13 (July), 317–323.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niemi, R. and Wright, J.R. (1987), Voting cycles and the structure of individual preferences Social Choice and Welfare 4, 73–183.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norpoth, H. (1979), The parties come to order! Dimensions of preferential choice in the West German Electorate, 1961–1976, American Political Science Review 73(3), 724–736.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierce, R. (1996), French Presidential Elections Survey, 1988 (computer file). ICPSR version. Ann Arbor, MI: Roy Pierce, University of Michigan (producer), 1995. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research, 1996.

    Google Scholar 

  • Radcliff, B. (1997), Collective preferences in presidential elections, Electoral Studies 13, 50–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Regenwetter, M., Falmagne, J.-C. and Grofman, B. (1999), A stochastic model of preference change and its application to 1992 Presidential Election panel data, Psychological Review 106(2), 362–384.

    Google Scholar 

  • Regenwetter, M. and Grofman, B. (1998a), Approval voting, Borda winners, and Condorcet winners: Evidence from seven elections, Management Science 44 (April), 520–533.

    Google Scholar 

  • Regenwetter, M. and Grofman, B. (1998b), Choosing subsets: A size-independent probabilistic model and the quest for a social welfare order, Social Choice and Welfare 15(3), 423–443.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1958), The paradox of voting and congressional rules for voting on amendments, American Political Science Review 52, 349–366.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1982), Liberalism Against Populism: A Confrontation Between the Theory of Democracy and the Theory of Social Choice. San Francisco, CA: W.H. Freeman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saari, D. (1995), Basic Geometry of Voting. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N.J. (1978), Generic instability of majority rule, Review of Economic Studies 50, 695–705.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N.J. (1995), Coalition politics: A formal model and empirical analysis, Journal of Theoretical Politics 7, 245–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N.J., Grofman, B. and Feld, S.L. (1988), The core and the stability of group choice in spatial voting games, American Political Science Review 82(1), 195–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A.K. (1966), A possibility theorem on majority decisions, Econometrica 34, 491–499.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A.K. and Pattanaik, P. (1969), Necessary and sufficient conditions for rational choice under majority decision, Journal of Economic Theory 1, 178–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K.A. (1979), Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models, American Journal of Political Science 23, 27–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K.A. and Bonchek, M.S. (1997), Analyzing Politics: Rationality, Behavior and Institutions. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tanguiane, A.S. (1991), Aggregation and representation of preferences: Introduction to the mathematical theory of democracy, Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tovey, C. (1990), The almost surely shrinking yolk, Working Paper. School of Industrial and Systems Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology.

  • Tovey, C. (1992), The probability of an undominated central voter in 2-dimensional spatial majority voting, Social Choice And Welfare 9(1), 43–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tovey, C. (1997) Probabilities of preferences and cycles with super majority rules, Journal of Economic Theory 75, 271–279.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsetlin, I. and Regenwetter, M. (in press.) On the probabilities of correct or incorrect majority preference relations, Social Choice and Welfare.

  • Tullock, G. (1981), Why so much stability? Public Choice 37(2), 189–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Deemen, A. (1999), The probability of the paradox of voting for weak preference orders, Social Choice and Welfare 16, 171–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Deemen, A. and Vergunst, N. (1998), Empirical evidence of paradoxes of voting in Dutch elections, Public Choice 97, 475–490.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weissberg, R. (1978), Collective vs. dyadic representation, American Political Science Review 72 (June), 535–547.

  • Williamson, O. and Sargent, T.J. (1967), Social choice: A probabilistic approach, Economic Journal 77, 797–813.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Regenwetter, M., Adams, J. & Grofman, B. On the (Sample) Condorcet Efficiency of Majority Rule: An alternative view of majority cycles and social homogeneity. Theory and Decision 53, 153–186 (2002). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1021215903030

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1021215903030

Navigation