Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Life after the regime: market instability with the fall of the US food regime

  • Published:
Agriculture and Human Values Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The US food regime maintained some degree of stability in terms of prices and production levels for commodities in the world economy. This food regime, resting on supply management policy, began to falter in the early 1970s. In the late-1980s and 1990s, notable changes occurred in the world economy regarding agriculture as the food regime became more market-oriented. The end of the twentieth century saw the breakdown of many institutions, organizations, and international agreements that had tried to stabilize prices and production from 1945 to 1975. This paper examines this period of change (roughly 1960–2010) and explores the effects on five commodities: cocoa, coffee, corn, soybeans, and wheat. These commodities offer important points of comparison. First, while cocoa, coffee, and wheat were regulated by international organizations and agreements, corn and soybeans were not. Second, the US dominated the international corn and soybean markets, but the cocoa, coffee, and wheat markets were much more competitive. And third, corn, soybeans, and wheat were commodities largely produced in the core of the world economy, while cocoa and coffee were produced in the periphery. Thus, comparing the effect of the fall of the US food regime on these commodities reveals the importance of previous regulation, the level of market competition, and geographic origin in the world economy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The full period of the analysis is about 1947–2010, which covers the rise and fall of the US food regime. The shift in the food regime occurred in the early- to mid-1970s, as the regime began to falter (Friedmann 1982). Since we are especially interested in this period of change, we focus on the period 1960–2010. Additionally, our data on world commodity prices comes from the World Bank and extends back to only 1960.

  2. Friedmann (1983) bases the emergence of the first food regime on the formation of a world wheat market, particularly in the coordination of prices. By contrast, Winders (2009b) bases the emergence of the regime on when the national and international policies forming the basis for free trade in agriculture took hold (e.g., the Anglo-French Treaty of 1860). Thus, one view focuses on market structures while the other focuses on economic policies.

  3. Although, Winders (2009a) shows that the gradual retrenchment of supply management policy in the US began in 1954 and continued through the early 2000s.

  4. In this respect, we see food regimes as connected to cycles of hegemony in the world economy. Friedmann (2009, p. 338), for example, points out the fundamental connection between financial crises and crises of hegemony, and she poses the question, “If the international monetary system is not stabilized, can there be any food regime?”

  5. Polanyi’s (1957) discussion of shifts between international regimes of free trade and state regulation helps to shed light on the process through which regimes take shape and change. In particular, the extent and kind of state intervention—whether assuming the form of national regulation or neoliberal policies supporting laissez faire market self-regulation—calls forth forces that push in the opposite direction. On the one hand, Polanyi notes that attempts to achieve the utopian “orthodox” free market eventually wreak havoc on society as well as on nature. As a result, movements opposing free market forces attempt to protect people and land to contain the destruction created by the market. On the other hand, “self-protection against the market limits the maneuver and, therefore, short-term profitability of capital” (Friedmann 1995, p. 15). This likewise creates opposition that seeks a change in the extent of state intervention. Therefore, opposition emerges within food regimes regardless of whether the regimes are oriented toward markets or regulation. This is the essence of Polanyi’s double movement.

  6. In the US, for example, production controls and price supports rested on “base acreage,” which restricted eligibility for subsidies and acreage allotments for particular commodities based on the farm’s historical production patterns. To maintain a steady base acreage for wheat, for example, a farm generally had to continue growing wheat. This helped to ensure fairly stable production levels, notwithstanding variability due to weather, etc.

  7. Of course, nations also adopted supply management policy due to domestic politics, which were sometimes tied to these issues (e.g., see Sheingate 2001). For a more extensive discussion of agriculture in GATT, see Friedmann (1982, 1995) or Winders (2009b).

  8. Finlayson and Zacher (1983, p. 386) note that six international commodity agreements were formulated, “for tin, sugar, coffee, cocoa, natural rubber and wheat.” Fridell (2007) suggests that cotton and wool also had commodity agreements. Certainly, international organizations existed to help coordinate markets for cotton (Quark 2013) and wool.

  9. Real prices (controlling for inflation) for these commodities declined steadily between 1960 and 1970. However, despite the relatively steady decline, trends in real prices for these commodities were devoid of sharp fluctuations.

  10. There have since been several wheat agreements, but they have not entailed the kind of regulations seen before 1970.

  11. Pendergrast (1999, p. 363) argues that the decline of the Cold War also affected the desire of the US to sign a new ICA, as the US became less concerned about the political repercussions of economic instability in Latin America.

  12. For an extensive discussion of the history and politics of US agricultural policy, including the FAIR Act, see Winders (2009a).

  13. Jaffee (2007, p. 48) points out the long-term decline in prices during part of this period: “Between 1980 and 2000, world prices for eighteen major export commodities fell by 25 % in real terms; the most dramatic declines occurred in sugar (for which the price fell by 77 %), cocoa (71 %), rice (61 %), and coffee (64 %).”

  14. We considered using a slightly different time period for coffee, 1971–1988, to correspond with the end of the ICA, which theoretically would have affected coffee prices. For this period (1971–1988), coffee prices showed an average annual variation of 23.3 % for Robusta and 24.4 % for Arabica. And using 1989–2010 for the final period, the average annual price variation for Robusta was 25.1 % and for Arabica was 22.5 %. We chose to use the same periodization for coffee as for the other commodities for the sake of clarity and ease of comparison.

  15. Consider for a moment an observation by Finlayson and Zacher (1983, p. 414): “As far as consuming countries are concerned, the matter which most affects their support for an ICA (international commodity agreement) is their ‘political’ concern to assist the LDC (less developed country) producers. While some do hope ICAs will prevent undesirable market fluctuations, they generally see little gain in these accords for themselves.” It is safe to assume that this was not true of what motivated wheat-consuming countries to participate in the IWA. These differing motives suggest different positions of power.

  16. Finlayson and Zacher (1983, p. 400) describe the voting structure set forth in 1973: “Importing and exporting members each had 1000 votes; the first 100 were divided equally between members of each group, and the remaining 900 were apportioned according to basic quotas in the case of exporters and import levels over 1969–1971 in the case of importers.” Under this system, the US would have had about 230 votes.

  17. By contrast, there were a number of economic and political levers that the US could use with other countries—even countries such as Canada—to compel a country to adhere to the IWA. Such levers were generally not available to Ghana or other cocoa-producing countries in the 1970s to compel the US to succumb to the interests of cocoa producers. It might be worth reminding ourselves that many cocoa-producing countries had only recently gained independence from European colonizers: Cameroon, 1960; Cote d’Ivoire, 1960; Ghana, 1957; and Nigeria, 1960. The relative strength and influence of these states in international relations compared to the US or European countries should be considered.

  18. Stiglitz (2002, p. 12, emphasis in original) notes that “the IMF was based on the recognition that markets often did not work well… and that there was a need for collective action at the global level for economic stability.” Therefore, from 1944 to the early 1970s, the strategies and goals of the IMF mirrored those of international commodity agreements and supply management: stabilize and coordinate the market and ensure adequate demand. Beginning in the mid-1970s, the goals and policies of the IMF changed to reflect the emerging neoliberalism that would dominate the last third of the twentieth century.

Abbreviations

CAP:

Common Agricultural Policy

FAIR Act:

Federal Agriculture Improvement and Reform Act

GATT:

General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

ICA:

International Coffee Agreement

ICCA:

International Cocoa Agreement

IMF:

International Monetary Fund

IWA:

International Wheat Agreement

NAFTA:

North American Free Trade Agreement

WTO:

World Trade Organization

References

  • Abdelal, R. 2007. Capital rules: The construction of global finance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barry, T. 1995. Zapata’s revenge. Boston, MA: South End Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bello, W. 2010. The food wars. London, UK: Verso Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farnsworth, H.C. 1956. International wheat agreements and problems, 1949–56. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 70(2): 217–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finlayson, J.A., and M.W. Zacher. 1983. The politics of international commodity regulation: The negotiation and operation of the international cocoa agreements. Third World Quarterly 5(2): 386–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fridell, G. 2007. Fair trade coffee: The prospects and pitfalls of market-driven social justice. Toronto, CA: University of Toronto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedmann, H. 1982. The political economy of food: The rise and fall of the postwar international food order. American Journal of Sociology 88(Supp): 249–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedmann, H. 1983. State policy and world commerce: The case of wheat, 1815 to present. In Foreign policy and the modern world-system, ed. P. McGowan and C. W. Kegley Jr, 125–155. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications.

  • Friedmann, H. 1995. Food politics: New dangers, new possibilities. In Food and agrarian orders in the world-economy, ed. P. McMichael, 15–33. Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedmann, H. 2005. From colonialism to green capitalism: Social movements and the emergence of food regimes. Research in Rural Sociology and Development 11: 227–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedmann, H. 2009. Moving food regimes forward: Reflections on symposium essays. Agriculture and Human Values 26: 335–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedmann, H., and P. McMcMichael. 1989. Agriculture and the state system: The rise and decline of national agricultures, 1870 to the present. Sociologia Ruralis 29(2): 93–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grant, R. 1993. Against the grain: Agricultural trade policies of the US, the European Community and Japan at the GATT. Political Geography 12(3): 247–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holt-Gimenez, E., and A. Shattuck. 2011. Food crises, food regimes and food movements: rumblings of reform or tides of transformation? Journal of Peasant Studies 38(1): 109–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopkins, R.F. 1992. Reform in the international food aid regime: The role of consensual knowledge. International Organization 46(1): 225–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffee, D. 2007. Brewing justice: Fair trade coffee, sustainability, and survival. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magnan, A. 2011. Bread in the economy of qualities: The creative reconstitution of Canada-UK commodity chain for wheat. Rural Sociology 76(2): 197–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCreary, I. 2011. Protecting the food insecure in volatile international markets: Food reserves and other policy options. Canadian Foodgrains Bank Occasional Paper. Winnipeg, MB: CFB. http://foodgrainsbank.ca/uploads/Food%20Security%20Price%20Volatility%20and%20Policy%20Responses-%20final%20-%2025%20March%2011.pdf. Accessed on 19 January 2015.

  • McMichael, P. 2005. Global development and the corporate food regime. Research in Rural Sociology and Development 11: 265–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McMichael, P. 2009. A food regime genealogy. Journal of Peasant Studies 36(1): 139–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pechlaner, G., and G. Otero. 2008. The third food regime: Neoliberal globalism and agricultural biotechnology in North America. Sociologia Ruralis 48(4): 351–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pechlaner, G., and G. Otero. 2010. The neoliberal food regime: Neoregulation and the new division of labor in North America. Rural Sociology 75(2): 179–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pendergrast, M. 1999. Uncommon grounds: The history of coffee and how it transformed our world. New York, NY: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi, K. 1957. The great transformation: The political and economic origins of our time. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pritchard, B. 2009. The long hangover from the second food regime: a world-historical interpretation of the collapse of the WTO Doha Round. Agriculture and Human Values 26: 297–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quark, A.A. 2013. Global rivalries: standards wars and the transnational cotton trade. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Robin, M. 2012. The world according to Monsanto. New York, NY: The New Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheingate, A.D. 2001. The rise of the agricultural welfare state: Institutions and interest group power in the United States, France, and Japan. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E. 2002. Globalization and its discontents. New York, NY: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallerstein, I. 1974. The modern world-system: Capitalist agriculture and the origins of the European world-economy in the sixteenth century. New York, NY: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walton, J.K., and D. Seddon. 1994. Free markets and food riots: The politics of global adjustment. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Winders, B. 2009a. The politics of food supply: US agricultural policy in the world economy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winders, B. 2009b. The vanishing free market: The formation and spread of the British and US food regimes. Journal of Agrarian Change 9(3): 315–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We appreciate comments from Rick Rubinson, as well as the careful reading and comments by the anonymous reviewers.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bill Winders.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Winders, B., Heslin, A., Ross, G. et al. Life after the regime: market instability with the fall of the US food regime. Agric Hum Values 33, 73–88 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10460-015-9596-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10460-015-9596-9

Keywords

Navigation